Update information transfer economics

Page 1

​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​ ​UPDATE:​ ​INFORMATION​ ​TRANSFER​ ​ECONOMICS In​ ​the​ ​right​ ​frame,​ ​economies​ ​radically​ ​simplify

I was reading ​Simon Wren-Lewis on productivity​, ​this out of NECSI​, as well as ​this from David Andolfatto on monetary policy. It sent me down memory lane with some of my posts (linked below)​ ​where​ ​I've​ ​talked​ ​about​ ​various​ ​ways​ ​to​ ​frame​ ​macro​ ​data. The thing is that certain ways of looking at the data can cause you to make either more complicated or less complicated models. And more complicated models don't always seem to be​ ​better​ ​at​ ​forecasting. Because we tend to think of the Earth at rest, we have to add ​Coriolis and centrifugal "pseudo forces" to Newton's law because it is a non-inertial frame. In an inertial frame, Newton's laws simplify. Because ancient astronomers thought not only that they were seeing circles in the sky, but that the Earth was at rest (in the center) they had to add epicycle upon epicycle to the motions of planets. In Copernicus's frame (with a bit of help from Kepler and Newton), the solar system is much​ ​simpler​ ​(on​ ​the​ ​time​ ​scale​ ​of​ ​human​ ​civilization). Now let me stress that this is just a possibility, but maybe macroeconomic models are complex because people are looking at the data using the wrong frame and seeing a complex data series? As I mentioned above, I have written several posts on how different ways of framing the data — different​ ​models​ ​—​ ​can​ ​affect​ ​how​ ​you​ ​view​ ​incoming​ ​data.​ ​Here​ ​is​ ​a​ ​selection:

https://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2017/03/the-recovery-and-using-models-to-fr ame.html


https://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2017/04/macroeconomics-has-no-equilibriu m-data.html

https://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2017/04/productivity-growth-and-verdoorns-l aw.html

https://informationtransfereconomics.blogspot.com/2017/04/growth-regimes-lowflation-and-dyna mic.html One thing that ties these posts together is that not only do I use the dynamic equilibrium model as an alternative viewpoint to the viewpoints of economists, but that the dynamic equilibrium model​ ​radically​ ​simplifies​ ​these​ ​descriptions​ ​of​ ​economies. What some see as the output of complex models with puzzles become almost laughably simple exponential growth plus shocks. In fact, not much seems to have happened in the US economy at all since WWII except ​women entering the workforce — the business cycle fluctuations are trivially​ ​small​ ​compared​ ​to​ ​this​ ​effect.


We might expect our description of economies to radically simplify when you have the right description. In fact, ​Erik Hoel has formalized this in terms of effective information: delivering the most​ ​information​ ​about​ ​the​ ​state​ ​of​ ​the​ ​system​ ​using​ ​the​ ​right​ ​agents. Whether or not you believe Hoel about causal emergence — that these simplifications must arise — we know we are encoding the most data with the least amount of information because the dynamic equilibrium models described above for multiple different time series can be represented​ ​as​ ​functions​ ​of​ ​each​ ​other. If​ ​one​ ​time​ ​series​ ​is​ ​exp(g(t))​,​ ​then​ ​another​ ​time​ ​series​ ​exp(f(t))​ ​is​ ​given​ ​by f(t)​ ​=​ ​c​ ​g(a​ ​t​ ​+​ ​b)​ ​+​ ​d​ ​t​ ​+​ ​e And​ ​if​ ​Y​ ​=​ ​f(X)​,​ ​then​ ​H(Y)​ ​≤​ ​H(X)​. [​ed.​ ​H(X)​ ​is​ ​the​ ​information​ ​entropy​ ​of​ ​the​ ​random​ ​variable​ X ​ ​] Now this only works for a single shock in the dynamic equilibrium model (the coefficients ​a ​and b ​adjust the relative widths and centroids of the single shocks in the series defined by ​f and ​g​). But as I mentioned above, most of the variation in the US time series is captured by a single large​ ​shock​ ​associated​ ​with​ ​women​ ​entering​ ​the​ ​workforce. The dynamic equilibrium frame not only radically simplifies the description of the data, but radically reduces the information content of the data. But the kicker is that this would be true regardless​ ​of​ ​whether​ ​you​ ​believe​ ​the​ ​derivation​ ​of​ ​the​ ​dynamic​ ​equilibrium​ ​model​ ​or​ ​not. You don't have to believe there's a force called gravity that happens between any two things with mass to see how elliptical orbits with the sun at one focus radically simplifies the description of the solar system. Maybe there's another way to get those elliptical orbits. But you'd definitely avoid making a new model that requires you to look at the data as being more complex (i.e. a higher​ ​information​ ​content). This is all to say the dynamic equilibrium model bounds the relevant complexity of macroeconomic models. ​I've discussed this before here​, but that was in the context of a particular effect. The dynamic equilibrium frame bounds the relevant complexity of all possible macroeconomic models. If a model is more complex than the dynamic equilibrium model, then it has to perform better empirically (with a smaller error, or encompass more variables with roughly the same error). More complex models should also reduce to the dynamic equilibrium model​ ​in​ ​some​ ​limit​ ​if​ ​only​ ​because​ ​the​ ​dynamic​ ​equilibrium​ ​model​ ​describes​ ​the​ ​data​ ​[1]. ... Footnotes:


[1] It is possible for effects to conspire to yield a model that looks superficially like the dynamic equilibrium model, but is in fact different. A prime example is a model that yields a dynamic equilibrium shock as the "normal" growth rate and the dynamic equilibrium "normal" as shocks. Think of a W-curve: are the two up strokes the normal, or the down? Further data should show that eventually you either have longer up stokes​ ​or​ ​down​ ​strokes,​ ​and​ ​it​ ​was​ ​possible​ ​you​ ​were​ ​just​ ​unlucky​ ​with​ ​the​ ​data​ ​you​ ​started​ ​with.


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.