Equilibrium #5 - Challenges for the new economy

Page 1

INSIDE:

Challenges for the new economy

Inequality: lost in the long grass? Opinions of the York Professor who foresaw the crisis Global warming: how to take it on, by an economist!

1


Contents Global round-up // 4 Economic means of preventing global warming // 6 Unemployment in Recession // 8 What’s a Summer Internship with the University like? // 10 Macroeconomic Policy and the Credit Crisis // 11 Feedback: how to turn it to your advantage // 13 Challenges for the new economy: scaling the fiscal cliff // 15 The Unsung Heroes and Heroines – The Entrepreneurs // 19 Inequality - So What? //21 But, Justice - So What? // 23 Article references available at www.yorkeconomicssociety.co.uk

2

Spring 2013


Economics Society The University of York A Brief Message

from the President and Vice-President of the University of York Economics Society In an ever-globalizing world, there has never been a better time to be interested in economics. Laying the foundations of trade, development, environment and culture, the study of economics seamlessly underpins the choices we make and the consequences we endure. EconSoc was founded on the principal of supporting students, and it is with a focus on employability, advice and networking that the Economics Society continues to thrive, with over 1000 members contributing to a society run by students, for students. In November last year, a new committee was elected which kick-started our first social: The Clash of the Titans. With an impressive turnout of over 200 students, the committee members were delighted to see so many students representing the society in a frenetic night with two other well-known societies. Following on with events such as a careers seminar for first-years, a commercial awareness talk and joint coverage of the 2012 US elections, the society was once again pleased to see rows of economists take time out to attend our ‘Money Never Sleeps’ film

night. Over 150 members of the society were greeted with popcorn, pizza and beverages, and we are especially thankful to the joint efforts of both social secretaries for their vast contributions to its success. It is the dedication of our members that continue to make EconSoc a success, but we don’t intend to stop there. The committee has many more events for you to look forward to, including a module choices talk, a charity social, more skills talks by employers and a Women’s social towards the end of this term. We hope you enjoy the cumulative efforts of editors, writers and academics in our latest issue of Equilibrium, and that you will join us in the future for more outstanding events. Until next time, The EconSoc Committee President: James Daveney Vice-President: Josh Carson

Editors:

Want to write for EQ? Article submissions are more than welcome, please send to econsoc. editors@live.com

Graphic design:

James Daveney, Dominic Falcão and James Lomas

Jessica Ochalek

Printing:

Copyeditor:

Daniel Howdon

3


Worldwide Economic Update

By Usama Polani, 1st Year Economics

Abenomics: a solution to Japan’s economic woes? The newly appointed Japanese Prime Minister, Shinzo Abe, is hoping that his brand of economic thinking – reflating the economy via monetary, fiscal and structural remedies – is the solution to Japan’s ongoing economic problems of entrenched deflation, accompanied by low GDP growth and interest rates close to their zero nominal bound. His philosophy is that expansionary monetary policy cannot work when demand for borrowing is low in the private sector and that, to tackle this problem, demand must be provided by the government in the form of a fiscal stimulus. His plan is to guarantee this using the asset purchases scheme, operated by the Bank of Japan (BoJ). His belief in structural reforms (including entering into trade agreements such as the Trans-Pacific Partnership) is highlighted by their integration within a government document, to be regularly reviewed by him and the BoJ governor. His plans are helped by the early retirement of the current governor, Masaaki Shirakawa, who has been reluctant to agree to a more aggressive monetary stance. This has allowed Mr Abe to appoint a new governor, Haruhiko Kuroda, who more

4

closely shares his belief in bold monetary easing. His deputyelect, Kikuo Iwata, even supports more extreme measures, such as the large-scale purchases of foreign bonds to cheapen the yen (which many see as overvalued) to bolster the economy. This aggressive stance on monetary policy has led to some countries fearing the effect of a devalued yen on their exports. Whether Mr Abe will meet his self-assigned 2% inflation target and also rescue Japan’s economy is yet to be seen but, even if successful, at what cost to others might this come?

The end of the Millennium Development Goals, and what comes next… As the 2015 deadline for the fulfilment of Millennium Development Goals (MDGs) approaches, it provides an apposite moment to reflect on the worldwide success of thwe goals, as well as to consider what should come next. While three of the eight goals have been achieved, progress has been uneven both across and within countries: while countries such as Brazil have already achieved many of the goals, Benin is expected not to reach any. Furthermore, the halving of the number of people living

Spring 2013

in absolute poverty, the World Bank suggests, was mostly thanks to progress in countries such as China and India, while countries in Sub-Saharan Africa have only reduced poverty by 1%. Although aid from developed countries towards the completion of the goals has been rising consistently, it has been shown that more than half goes to debt relief, while much of the remainder goes to disaster relief and military aid, leading many to question their effect on assisting development. There has also been criticism that the MDGs fail to take into account the need for sustainable development. In July 2012 the Secretary-General launched his High-level Panel of Eminent Persons to provide guidance and recommendations on the post-2015 development agenda. They are expected to release a report in May, which will provide an indication of the new post-2015 goals, and of whether the lessons from the implementation of MDGs have been taken on board.

Argentina vs the IMF on inflation Since the Argentine government took control of the country’s national statistics office in 2007, discrepancies between the official inflation numbers and those


reported by independent economists have ranged up to 15 percentage points. Having censured the country for such inaccuracies, the IMF has given the government until September 29 to address these problems, stating that, if it fails to do so, it could face punishments ranging from suspension of voting rights to possible expulsion from the IMF. With labour unions protesting the disparity between wage increases and true inflation, the government has announced that it has ordered supermarkets to enact a price freeze for two months. The government has realised that this could escalate into social unrest and, with an election imminent, has announced that a new price index will be introduced in the final quarter of 2013. It is unclear whether such a move will meet the IMF’s demands, with the relationship between the Fund and the Argentine government already fraught following President Cristina Kirchner’s public condemnation of the Fund in the aftermath of the country’s economic meltdown in 2001. The potential for economic and social instability after the imposition of this new price index remains clear, with any new estimates likely to be treated with suspicion.

Obama and income inequality Barack Obama‘s attempts to reduce income inequality have continued, with a proposal to raise the federal minimum wage by 24% to

a nominal $9 an hour by 2015, and to index this figure to inflation thereafter. The US’s federal minimum wage is, at present, one of the lowest in the OECD, was last increased by Congress in 2009, and has historically been allowed to be eroded in real terms by inflation. The move by Obama has sparked a flurry of debate: while mainstream economic theory suggests that such a move could lead to unemployment, much empirical analysis has thrown this into doubt. Although this debate will continue to rage on in academic circles, whether the proposed increase takes place is ultimately dependent on the support of the Republicans, in a highly-charged political climate which is apt to suffer gridlock.

Moody’s being moody The UK has lost its coveted AAA credit rating from one agency, and has been downgraded to AA1. Moody’s cited the reason for the downgrade as expected sluggish growth, due to weak global activity and the drag from the domestic “deleveraging process”. Although the change will not significantly increase Britain’s ability to borrow, it raises the question of whether the coalition’s path of severe austerity is working. George Osborne remains adamant that this move further motivates him to continue his fiscal consolidation, noting that deficit reduction policies are cited by Moody’s as part of the reason why the UK’s credit wor-

thiness is still “extremely high”. Others are less confident of the strategy, citing growing research from bodies such as the IMF that aggressive austerity may not work, and recent figures showing that the economy contracted by 0.3% at the end of 2012.

Haggling over the EU budget and missing the real problems EU leaders have, after seemingly endless talks, finalised a new EU budget. While it only constitutes 2% of EU spending, the process is lengthened by both resistance from already indebted countries, as well as anger from others at a perception that the EU is trying to exempt itself from the austerity it has imposed on others. An axis led by Angela Merkel and David Cameron has already succeeded in trimming the 2014-2020 budgets by 3%. Although the European Parliament has already rejected the proposed budget, amidst possible suggestions of a possible review of the issue in two or three years, they continue to miss the real problems of the budget. The Common Agricultural Policy still makes up 40% of the budget, while agriculture only contributes less than 2% of GDP. Slashing these expenditures would free up resources for thriving industries while, at the same time, allow overall spending to be reduced.

5


Economic means of preventing global warming By Paul Schweinzer, Lecturer, Department of Economics

T

he disappointing series of failures to reach agreement among the 194 members of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change in Copenhagen (2009), Cancún (2010), Durban (2011), and Doha (2012) highlights the international impasse in preventing further global warming. Yet immediate action seems to be called for; recent research reports rapid reductions in ice mass balance from both Greenland and Antarctica with a projected sea-level rise of one to two metres by 2100. Since an estimated 160 million people live currently in locations less than one metre above sea level, the impact of such change on the world economy would be substantial. In new research, Beatrice Roussillon and I study and attempt to answer two questions arising in this context: i) How can incentives be provided to reduce harmful emissions to their socially efficient levels while not infracting upon productive efficiency? ii) What would this efficiency cost in percentage of our model-GDP? The present article outlines our answers to both. In our model environment, there are two ways to reduce emissions: by producing less or abating more. Our mechanism plays on these two aspects in order to achieve efficiency in both. Our an-swers to the above two questions involve a stylised contest among nations, rewarding the countries with the highest abatement efforts with some share of global output. In a nutshell, marginal pro-duction is ‘taxed’ to fund a prize pool, and marginal abate-

6

ment increases the probability of winning a share of this pool. By designing the contest parameters correctly, both equilibrium incentives can be set efficiently at the margin. This contest is based on a relative ranking of all nations’ abatement efforts. The precision with which this ranking is correct, i.e., the precision of mutual abatement monitoring, is one of the design parameters of our proposed mechanism. Since imperfect monitor-ing leaves an element of luck to winning, there is a lottery flavour to this competition. The main type of emissions we have in mind is greenhouse gases. These are widely seen as the main contributing factor to global warming. Emitted by one country as inherent part of the produc-tive process, they are distributed around the globe regardless of where they were produced and, as such, present an externality. A reduction of emissions benefits all countries but the costs of such reductions are carried individually. This generates a classic free-rider problem in which each coun-try would like the threat of global warming removed but none is ready to pay the cost. The environmental literature employs three main approaches to overcome the inefficient emissions abatement problem: commandand-control regulation, quantityoriented market approaches,

Spring 2013

and tax-or-pricing regimes. The approach adopted by the 187 signatories of the Kyoto protocol is the quantity-oriented market approach targeting a reduction based on developed countries’ emissions in 1990. The treaty, however, failed to obtain ratification by major players including, most promi-nently, the United States. Moreover, the concern was

expressed that developing countries might have ratified the treaty without the intention of keeping emissions in check. This mars the current emissions reduction reality with the dual frustrations of insufficient participation and diluted objectives.


In a nutshell, marginal production is ‘taxed’ to fund a prize pool, and marginal abatement increases the probability of winning a share of this pool. Yale economist William Nordhaus is among the most prominent advocates of the implementation of market-based instruments and, more specifically, a world-harmonised tax on each ton of CO2 emissions. This proposal presents many advantages: it can achieve efficiency at the world level, it is simple to implement, and it is a well-known instrument. With a harmonised tax, however, each country pays the same price/tax for a ton of CO2 emissions regardless of its revenue and responsibility for climate change. This could be particularly hard on poor countries and reduce their incentives to join any international agreement. Moreover, there is no guarantee that the solution will be cost effective. Our mechanism offers the ability to provide individualised incentives to each country to abate efficiently. A harmonised tax is based on the ‘polluter pays’ principle whereas our mecha-nism is driven by a ‘cleaner wins’ principle which we believe could improve participation by devel-oping countries. The reason is that there are many ‘low hanging fruits’ in developing countries rep-resenting easy abatement possibilities and thus high chances to win the competition we suggest.

achieved. To get a feeling for the magnitudes implied by our proposed mechanism we build a small Mickey-Mouse example of the world economy just consisting of two independent nations (blocks), each producing half the world GDP (of $61tr in 2008). In this simple example, our mechanism reaches efficiency—at various specific and agreed upon monitoring levels—at a minimal transfer level of at 1.1-2.7% of individual GDP. Although these still imply enormous two-player payments of $0.4-0.8tr, these transfers do not seem to be outside of the politically feasible range.

for punishment strategies such as exclusive trade agreements or environmental standards excluding agreement de-serters from trade within the agreement. In reality, of course, reaching agreement on and commit-ting to the efficient mechanism’s parameters, the necessary transfers and the exact specification of the contest still present a formidable political task.

The prevention of free-riding on the agreement, i.e., not joining the agreement but benefiting from the cleaner environment the agreement brings about without contributing, is crucial for any inter-national environmental agreement. The mechanism we propose can theoretically ensure universal participation through an insurance property of the redistributive contest mechanism. Specifically, we show that for sufficiently income-shock-averse players, the risk-pooling through redistribution implied by the proposed mechanism can assure participation without the need

A harmonised tax is based on the ‘polluter pays’ principle whereas our mechanism is driven by a ‘cleaner wins’ principle which we believe could improve participation by developing countries.

To a large extent, however, we feel that any mechanism attempting to solve the emissions problem will have to face a variant of these problems. We attempt to name and discuss these challenges—and provide first results showing that

a mechanism along the lines we indicate can in theory correct nations’ combined incentives to emit too much while abating too little.

Estimating the cost of reaching the efficient outcome in a realistic model is conceptually and com-putationally difficult, even if a meaningful agreement on the model parameters could be

7


Unemployment in Recession By Neil Dodd, 3rd Year Economics

‘Why is youth unemployment so much lower in Germany than in Britain and Southern Europe? ’ ‘Which policies are most effective in combating unemployment in recessions? ’

Professor Pissarides is a Cypriot economist. He is currently a School Professor of Economics at the London School of Economics. His research interests focus on several topics of macroeconomics, notably labour, economic growth, and economic policy. In 2010, he was awarded the Nobel Prize in economics, jointly with Peter A Diamond and Dale Mortensen, for his contributions to the theory of search frictions and macroeconomics. ‘Unemployment in Recession’ by Chris Pissarides, the 2012 Royal Economic Society (RES) Public Lecture, was delivered at the Royal Institution, London at 5pm on Thursday 22 November and at the University of York at 5pm on Wednesday 5 December

T

he University of York hosted this year’s Royal Economic Society annual public lecture. The topic of discussion was ‘Unemployment in Recession’, with a particular focus on young people. 2010 Nobel prize-winning economist Professor Christopher Pissarides of the London School of Economics delivered an interesting and good-humoured talk. A lecture delivered by such a respected economist on a currently relevant issue attracted an eager and varied audience. The following questions were some of those addressed during the lecture: ‘Why are nearly half of young people in Spain out of work? ’

8

The Nobel laureate also outlined key elements of an active labour market policy for young people. This, he suggested, could include extending education places: through universities and colleges offering more applied and shorter courses; providing specially designed training; subsidising self-employment or recruitment of unemployed youths by companies; and teaching young people how to look for and learn about jobs.

ment levels have actually fallen since 2008. How can it be that certain countries are barely affected, and others virtually ruined? In times like these, urgent policy action is needed to avoid long-term unemployment, which destroys talent and creates social problems.

Supply and demand analysis is the conventional method used to explain the differences between the changes in countries’ unemployment levels caused by the recession. Although the framework is sufficient when studying technology or tax, the model fails on several counts when looking at unemployment. First, the framework is inadequate at predicting the impact of a recession. The model demonstrates that a Professor Pissarides started by recession will cause hours of work discussing the vast differences (employment) to fall slightly, and in the unemployment levels of the real wage rate to fall drastiOECD countries, five years prior cally. However, economic data and to the recession. Before the recesintuition implies that the exact sion, Britain had unemployment opposite occurs: employment falls relatively under control. Only 5% significantly and wages hardly of the whole workforce and 14% of fall. Second, supply and demand young people were unemployed. analysis does not take into account Even in normal economic times, many features of the modern youth unemployment is higher labour market. Much emphasis than adult unemployment, but in has recently been placed on the a recession the gap widens and institutional structure of counyoung people stay out of work tries with particular reference to for too long. In 2008 we were hit trade unions, the structure of the by the worst recession since the benefits system and employment 1930s, although unemployment legislation. levels didn’t reach that of the 1980s recession. Spain has been hit hardest in terms of unemployment and has suffered detrimental effects: unemployment has risen by nearly 10% and three times as many young people, compared to adults, are now out of work. The recession, however, barely affected Germany, and youth unemployPhoto: Telegraph, July 30th 2012

Spring 2013


As a result of this, Professor Pissarides has spent much of his academic life developing ‘search and matching’ theory. He explained how this framework deals with some of the many issues that conventional supply and demand analysis cannot. Traditionally, economists assume full information: this is wherein Professor Pissarides believes the problem lies. The key difference with ‘search and matching’ theory is the realisation that there is a vast amount of information that needs to be digested in labour markets, and that in reality we can never reach the market-clearing equilibrium in the absence of perfect informa-

Just as they are not expected to marry their first boyfriend or girlfriend, they should not be expected to take their first job and stick with it forever. tion. Workers in the labour market, in conventional theory, are uniform products: in reality this isn’t true. Workers are heterogeneous and one worker’s labour may differ from another’s. There are also many other costs involved when entering employment, and changing jobs can often involve mobility costs (such as moving an entire family). People also have varied preferences: different jobs

are preferred by different people. Professor Pissarides refers to the factors that slow down the adjustment from one equilibrium to another as ‘frictions’. The term ‘search’ refers to the process by which firms and workers learn about each other and get together for productive employment. A ‘match’ is a job between a worker and a firm. Professor Pissarides explained that youth unemployment is almost always higher than adult unemployment because young workers start unemployed. They have relatively little idea about their talents and need the chance to experiment and learn. A young person may also not want to take the first job that comes along. Professor Pissarides believes the way in which we should tackle this problem is by allowing young workers to go ‘job shopping’. An ideal labour market is one where young people are given the opportunity to ‘job shop’ until they discover what they are good at. Professor Pissarides joked: ‘Just as they are not expected to marry their first boyfriend or girlfriend, they should not be expected to take their first job and stick with it forever’. The concept of ‘job shopping, he claimed,’ explains why youth unemployment is greater than adult unemployment in normal times. A desirable market is one that provides this experience, and is flexible by having a high degree of job turnover. This market allows employers to take advantage of new job opportunities and create many jobs for young people to try out.

A natural outcome of this process is unemployment: it is normal to become unemployed for brief periods during this shopping period. Germany is the most successful of the major countries in its ratio of youth to adult unemployment. They have developed a very elaborate subsidised apprentice system for young people. However, Italy and Greece are the least successful: both countries have rigid labour markets with a lot of job protection for adults and low levels of job turnover. Therefore, employers aren’t willing to hire people and, as a result, young people struggle to gain experience of work. Fundamentally, in rigid labour markets or in recessions, young workers stay unemployed for too long. But, Professor Pissarides claims, this is when we need labour markets to be the most flexible, and we need active labour market policies. The talk was rounded off by a warm drinks reception, allowing A-level students the opportunity to ask any questions about economics at York. There were a whole host of people from the department present, including undergraduates, PhD students and lecturers. Everyone also had the opportunity to question Professor Pissarides, and in some cases even got the odd photograph.

Photo: “The Young and the Unemployed” by “Odins-Girl”

9


What’s a Summer Internship with the University like? By James Daveney, 2nd Year Economics

T

hroughout most of my Summer I had an internship in the Ron Cooke Hub on Heslington East (you know, the ‘other’ campus?) My time there was spent with only a handful of people in a very small office in a flagship building less than two years old. There are many stakeholders in the Ron Cooke Hub, from start-up companies and academic departments to Science Park offices and the White Rose Enterprise Group. Truly an inspirational place to be. And it challenges you. Over the course of my internship, I helped organise a community fete in and around the Hub, which was attended by over 600 people. I learned about marketing, product

I learned about marketing, product development, the internal politics of running the Hub and completed tasks outside my comfort zone. development, the internal politics of running the Hub and completed tasks outside my comfort zone. This might all sound to you like a work-intensive internship, one where you are taught how to do something and expected to do just that for the next eight or twelve weeks. I was not taught the basics, I had to work them out for myself, and had to find the style of work that best suited me. This was, how-

10

ever, one of the great things about working in the Hub. Would I work an extra few hours to make a programme of events for the people attending the community fete? Would I go home and leave people to run around the Hub like mad chickens the next day? Luckily, I did the former. I am not saying everyone has to put in extra time during internships: my point is that working in the Hub made me want to put in more effort, as I could see the great things that people were doing around me and I wanted to match that. It might sound like I am trying to sell the Ron Cooke Hub to you and – at least partly – I am. I am also trying to sell internships with the University. I think they are extremely valuable to everyone involved: just look at the people who benefited from there being an internship at the Hub this Summer: First, the person doing the Internship. In this case that was me, but it could be anyone in the future as there will be new opportunities every year. I learned more about the importance of networking, making deadlines and how the University works – which was not very well at times. Second, the Hub. The office in which I was working now had the staff to assist in events, to make events of their own and to help with the day-to-day running of the Hub. The other stakeholders in the Hub like business staff, academics

Spring 2013

and the local community gained from this too. Third, the Careers Service. They can use the internships this summer to advertise what they have done to help students become more employable. The Service can then use them to help promote other opportunities they offer. Want to know how I got the internship in the first place? Head to York’s Interactive Careers Service website and sign up to get emails about everything they have to offer. The Service is in charge of the Student Internship Bureau, who, as the name suggests, organise all on- and off-campus internships. These are throughout the year, not only in the summer, and are highly flexible in terms of hours you can work, skills you can gain and work you will be enjoying.


The Careers Service website initially had about fifteen internships on offer: I applied to two, using a very simple application form, submitting my CV which was to be passed to a potential manager. I did not hear back from the other application, but it did not matter as I had an interview scheduled at the Hub. The interview itself was the most useful one I have ever had. This was chiefly because, for the first time, the interviewer – my soon to be manager – delved into the jobs and work experience I had listed on my CV. That is something that no other person had done before. I also gained a lot from a chat about the Hub after he had finished with his questions.

I was not taught the basics, I had to work them out for myself, and had to find the style of work that best suited me. So, in essence, I hope I have persuaded you of the value of internships during your University life. Yeah, sure, I could have spent my Summer back home raiding my Mum’s fridge every half an hour looking for food, whilst having barely anything else to do. But what would I have gained from that? Also, did I mention the pay? (This and the occasional free sandwiches were a factor in me applying for one in the first place.) It is a standard £230 a week, not bad at all for a student. Furthermore, I hope I have shown that, even though the work might be challenging at times, it is definitely worth the effort.

Macroeconomic Policy and the Credit Crisis Michael Wickens is a Professor of Economics at the University of York. He was formerly Managing Editor of The Economic Journal. He now serves as Specialist Advisor to the House of Lords Economic Affairs Committee. He is a Fellow of the Centre for Economic Policy Research, Fellow of the CESifo Group and is a consultant to the International Monetary Fund and the UN Food and Argiculture Organisation. Michael’s is the author ofMacroeconomic Theory: A Dynamic General Equilibrium Approach, (Princeton University Press).

A

central concern of macroeconomics is how best to conduct monetary and fiscal policy. Despite lengthy and authoritative expositions in macro textbooks, there is still no consensus on the answer. The current crisis in the eurozone, the UK government’s emphasis on bringing down its deficit and debt despite a double dip recession, and the switch of the Bank of England to unconventional monetary policies show how deep and unresolved the problem is. For several years, my research at York has focused on these issues. Before the eurozone crisis, I identified the problem that would come to engulf the eurozone. My diagnosis was that although the ECB had been successful in achieving its target for average inflation in the eurozone, its monetary policy was inappropriate for most eurozone countries. Until the euro crisis it was difficult to persuade the ECB that there was a problem with a single currency. Initially, joining the euro seemed

extremely beneficial to the weaker economies: Ireland grew by more than 40%, Spain and Portugal grew similarly, while Germany grew by only 10%. However, the price level in Ireland also rose by 40% and the price levels in Spain and Portugal grew by around 35%, while Germany’s rose only 5%. The problem was that – for countries with higher inflation than average – monetary policy was too loose and resulted in cheap credit, while – for countries with lower than average inflation – credit was much more expensive. As a result, countries like Greece, Ireland, Portugal and Spain borrowed far too much – much of it on residential construction – and are now paying the penalty. In short, the single currency has played a major part in causing the debt crisis. The solution that I recommended was that, having given up their monetary independence and still having an inappropriate monetary policy, they had to use tighter fiscal policy to compensate. In fact, because borrowing was cheap,

11


the financial crisis has tended to undermine the agencies’ credibility. My current research proposes a new way for a government and the financial markets to assess the credit rating of government debt. This is based on forecasting the future debt-GDP ratio and evaluating the probability that this exceeds the upper limit on sus-

their governments spent freely and debt-financed this. Even now the Commission is trying to impose a uniform fiscal policy on EU countries when what is required is a policy tailored to each country’s situation. A closely related issue is whether or not a government’s fiscal stance is sustainable. If not, it must change. In other research I proposed a way of determining this.

Because borrowing was cheap, governments spent freely and debt-financed this.

Based on the government budget constraint, the aim is to assess whether future expected budget surpluses are likely to be sufficient to pay off current government debt. I found that many EU countries have for many years had unsustainable fiscal stances, including countries, such as France, commonly thought to be in a healthy fiscal state.

sion. The basis of the government’s policy is the large structural deficit inherited from the previous government – due to a huge expansion of welfare benefits and spending on health that was financed by borrowing when it should have used taxes – and the concern that higher government borrowing would become increasingly expensive as the credit rating agencies would then downgrade their rating for the UK. Recent statements by the credit rating agencies have made this even more likely. This has raised the influence of the credit rating agencies on fiscal policy. How the credit rating agencies reach their judgements is a puzzle. At the same time, the fact that they gave a triple-A rating to both the UK and the US throughout

The UK government has been heavily criticised for seeming to be more concerned with reducing its deficit and debt than in borrowing more in order to deficit-finance a stimulus to the economy, the textbook recommendation in reces-

12

Spring 2013

How the credit rating agencies reach their judgements is a puzzle.

tainable debt. It appears, according to this research, that both the UK and the US should have had a credit downgrade from 2007, contrary to what the credit rating agencies have said. I hope that you will agree that all of this shows that macroeconomics is dealing with important and interesting issues that are worthy of your study. There are many other similar issues for you to research on in your PhD! Michael Wickens Professor of Economics University of York


how to turn it to your advantage By Jacco Thijssen, Chair Departmental Teaching Committee and Feedback Coordinator

W

e’ve all been there. You get a disappointing mark for an assignment and you feel frustrated. It is worth, however, taking a couple of minutes to examine how you react, as time and again we find that what distinguishes outstanding students is not their early marks, but their attitude to feedback. In fact, being able to use feedback in a constructive way is one of the most important transferable skills you can take with you when you leave York, and it is one that we take very seriously in the Department.

In fact, being able to use feedback in a constructive way is one of the most important transferable skills you can take with you when you leave York, and it is one that we take very seriously in the Department. We know from the NSS that feedback is high on your list of priorities, and it’s an area in which we’ve worked hard this year. In addition to helping you improve your grades (something we’re both interested in!), we also hope to better prepare you for your professional career, where independent learning and being able to spot for yourself when you’re not on the right track really comes into play.

When I speak of feedback here, I mean feedback on work that you are asked to engage with during term time. Our policy is clear on this – you will receive at least one piece of feedback per term per module. This can take various forms, such as comments on written work, or model solutions to problem sheets. The deal we strike Feedback truly is a two-way process. The deal between us is clear. You put a lot into your assignments, and we put a lot into designing feedback that helps you to (i) engage with learning, (ii) improve your understanding of the material, and (iii) allow you to develop a critical attitude to your own work. That seems fairly simple, but often the process breaks down, causing frustration for both parties.

instructions is something we work hard on in the Department, but it is difficult sometimes to place ourselves in the student’s shoes and imagine what it was like before we knew what we know. Therefore, if the goal of an essay/problem sheet is not clear, ask. 2. After finishing the task, but before handing it in, try to mark your own work. How good are you at critically assessing your own performance? It can be interesting to put this to the test. Before you hand in your next assignment, try to give yourself a mark for the work that you are going to submit and then compare with the actual result. This is an important skill, because in your professional career you

How to get the most out of feedback 1. Make sure the objectives of the task are clear to you. Remember that old piece of exam advice: ‘answer the question’? It’s well-acknowledged that students often put many hours of unproductive work into their studies (see, for example, Kember et al., 1996). It’s really important that, before you begin, you’re absolutely clear about what you’re being asked to do. Giving unambiguous

13


will have to be able to judge the quality of your own work before you send it to your manager/ team/client, etc. This is also where model solutions come in. These only make sense if you use them to compare to your own solutions. If your own assessment of your work is very different from that of the academic who has marked it or provided the model solutions, make sure you use our office hours to find out why.

When you get feedback, good or bad, make sure you spend sufficient time digesting it. If you’ve put considerable time into your assignment, don’t rush engaging with the feedback. 3. Upon the work being returned, try to square your own judgement with that of the academic using the comments provided. When you get feedback, good or bad, make sure you spend suf-

ficient time digesting it. If you’ve put considerable time into your assignment, don’t rush engaging with the feedback. Numerous studies show that often feedback is either not read at all (Hounsell, 1987) or not understood (Lea and Street, 1998). A quick example from my own experience might illustrate. In the first year module “Introduction to Statistical Theory”, each student hands in two problem sheets. I noticed during the spring term last year that the same group of students, on the whole, made the same mistakes in

There’s a common thread running through this article, and it’s this: if in doubt, ask. both problem sheets. That indicates that somewhere between my writing comments on student work and your receiving those and acting upon them, something does not always work. If parts of feedback that you receive aren’t clear, ask.

4. Use the feedback on your work to improve performance in your next piece of work. In my experience, becoming better at something you once found difficult is even more satisfying than doing something with ease from the outset. It means you’ve got some return on your investment. If you’ve had poor feedback, use it well, and turn it to your advantage. If in doubt, ask There’s a common thread running through this article, and it’s this: if in doubt, ask. Ask yourself if you’re clear what you’re being asked to do. Ask yourself what mark you’d give yourself. Ask yourself or your tutor how the mark was arrived at. Finally, when you get that feedback, ask yourself how you’re going to deal with it. And make sure you turn it to your advantage. References available online.

14

Spring 2013


Challenges for the new economy: scaling the fiscal cliff By Peter Spencer, Professor of Economics and Finance, Department of Economics

A

s the White House and Congress play politics on the brink of a fiscal cliff, doubts have inevitably emerged about the robustness of the US recovery. Will the uncertain outlook for US fiscal policy hold back business investment and consumer confidence? Will America follow Europe into recession as fiscal policy tightens? And how will all of this impact the UK? The US economy was allowed to recover‌ The experience of the Eurozone is not particularly illuminating

since unlike the US, its imbalances are internal rather than external. The UK offers a more interesting counterfactual since like the US it was unbalanced by a bubble in credit and asset prices and needs to make similar price and balance sheet adjustments. It offers an interesting comparison since it embarked on a programme of fiscal adjustment at an early stage of its recovery. Arguably, the UK did not have the luxury that the US did of waiting for the economy to recover fully before retrenching. Even so, this comparison reveals a lot about our own economy and where we are going wrong. ‌before being knocked back by fiscal retrenchment Many commentators have suggested that the disappointing nature of the UK recovery and retrenchment largely reflects the decision to attempt the fiscal adjustment before the private sector had time to recover. In contrast, the US allowed the household

sector to deleverage without the added pressure of the austerity programme, which has made this adjustment so much harder for UK households. Furthermore, the US allowed foreclosures and sales of newly built houses to push prices back into equilibrium, while in the UK these adjustments were eased by policy measures and forbearance on the part of lenders. During 2009 and 2010 over four million families lost their homes in the US, compared with 86 thousand in the UK. Following this brutal adjustment, the US housing market has bottomed and is now bouncing back strongly. The result, as the first two charts show, is that the US has been able to reduce its deficit in a similar way to the UK, but using market adjustments and growth-friendly policies rather than austerity. Similar contrasts are seen in the labour market. In the UK, employers and employees agreed short time working and other schemes to keep staff on as output fell,

The charts in this article show developments over the last decade and are extrapolated using the ITEM Club Winter Economic Forecast, published on 21 January.

15


while in the US employers took a sharp knife to payroll. Consequently unemployment rose much more rapidly in the US, approaching 10% of the labour force. The UK paid a price in terms of labour productivity, which fell sharply in the recession and has been very weak during the recovery phase. Although the recent growth in

of its competitors. The effect of sterling’s 2008/09 devaluation in bringing down our relative costs is very clear. Although the dollar has depreciated against the Euro and other countries, the downtrend in the costs of US firms is largely due to their high rate of productivity. They are winning back market share at home and abroad and

had changed until the Northern Rock collapsed six weeks later. Its programme of Quantitative Easing has focussed narrowly upon the gilt market, avoiding the purchases of residential mortgages and other securities that the Fed has made. The Funding for Lending Scheme is certainly an innovation for the Bank, but it leaves the

UK full time employment has been impressive, it is unlikely that this growth will be maintained if the economy remains in the doldrums. The worry is that firms that have held on to staff in the hope of an upturn will be disappointed and start to shed staff.

many are moving production back home from overseas. I think that the US should be able to keep the spectre of recession at bay despite the effect of the dysfunctional political system on consumer and corporate confidence.

banks with the credit risk while providing cheap funding.

Remarkably, US productivity and profitability hardly fell at all during the recession and have been very strong during the recovery phase, putting US producers in a very competitive position internationally. Labour cost inflation normally increases during a recession due to the cyclical fall in productivity, but the first of the charts shown below reveals that it actually fell in the US during the recession, in contrast to the experience of UK and other countries. The chart on the right of the next pair shows the level of each country’s labour costs measured in dollars, compared with those

16

The Fed led the way to recovery with innovative financial policies… Another contrast is evident in the sphere of monetary policy. The Fed has been much more innovative than the Bank of England in dealing with the financial crisis and supporting economic activity. It was quick off the mark when the money markets froze in August 2007, immediately recognising the threat to the banking system and the wider economy and flooding the money markets with liquidity. Instead, the Bank of England was transfixed by the bogey of moral hazard and did not accept that the game

Spring 2013

…putting the US economy in a good position to withstand a fiscal contraction Part of the problem admittedly lies in the very specific inflation remit set for the MPC by the HMTreasury. In contrast, the Fed has a dual mandate, involving both inflation and unemployment. This gives it a great deal of flexibility,


which it has used to the full. Last September the Fed’s rate-setting panel, the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) announced that it would make unlimited purchases of residential mortgages to stimulate household spending and the housing market until there was a significant improvement in the labour market. Then at its December 12th meeting the FOMC announced that it would keep interest rates close to zero until unemployment had fallen below 6.5% or until inflation was forecast to exceed 2.5%. The Fed’s switch to a pro-growth policy stance should have the effect of making the private sector more confident about future economic activity in the face of fiscal and other shocks, in the same way that its former anti-inflationary stance bolstered confidence in low and stable inflation. The UK Treasury and MPC… Now, with a new Governor designate, the Bank and the Treasury are in a position to reassess the remit. It is clear that although inflation targets initially worked well in stabilising price expectations, they passed their sell-by date around the turn of the millennium. With the benefit of hindsight it is now clear that a favourable supply-side shock taking the form of a fall in world consumer goods price inflation initially kept interest rates artificially low and helped stimulate a credit-fed bubble in asset prices. Then in the second half of the decade the shock turned negative as oil, food and other commodity prices pushed up to record highs, putting upward pressure on inflation and interest rates and crushing consumer spending power. With the economy in recession, the MPC faced an

invidious choice: between further depressing the economy and risking its reputation by allowing inflation to consistently overshoot the target. … should now adopt a more sensible target… Money GDP (MGDP) growth targets have emerged as the front runner in the debate about a new remit. The growth in MGDP is not difficult to understand: it is simply the sum of real GDP growth and inflation and thus gives equal weight to both. This is appropriate when inflationary expectations are well-anchored and the central bank can afford to give some weight to what is happening in the real economy. The main argument for a MGDP target is that it handles the effect of external supply side shocks very neatly. The basic idea as we know from macro lectures is that the central bank can control the money value of output but not the way that this is split between real

output and prices. This split is determined by the private sector. The central bank can however steer the inflation trend indirectly by setting the growth in the money value of output in line with the trend in real productive potential and a medium term inflation target. If an adverse supply side shock (like a rise in world commodity prices) occurs, then output falls below trend and inflation moves above trend for a while, with the opposite happening for a favourable shock. Either way, inflation departs temporarily from trend without seriously disrupting the real economy or damaging the central bank’s reputation. …to accommodate supply-side shocks… This is the textbook argument for the superiority of MGDP over inflation targets and seems compelling in current circumstances. Moreover, the money value of output is not just easier for the MPC to control, it is also much easier for the Office for National

The Bank of England on Threadneedle Street, London, England

17


quirks and would make MGDP give a misleadingly good signal if a spending boom was met from imports. It would make much more sense to target the growth in the money value of Total Final Expenditure.

Statistics (ONS) to measure than inflation. We naturally look at our income and expenditure in pounds and pence. Companies do the same for their management, as well as the taxman and shareholders. Splitting these values into real and price components is relatively straightforward for a manufacturing firm producing standardised that can be measured as physical quantities. However this is notoriously for service sector firms that have sales invoices and perhaps figures for payroll and hours worked but few tangibles to go on. Digital products, which have zero marginal cost, also present formidable measurement problems. …and handle measurement problems… The problems of measuring inflation in the consumer sector have been highlighted by the ONS proposals to change the methodology used to construct the RPI. Technically, it is very difficult to devise indices that do not suffer from an in-build upward bias. The RPI is particularly prone to this problem and has the awkward property

18

that it shows an increase in prices if they fluctuate during a period even if they return to where they were at the beginning! Indeed the advent of the new CPIH and the new RPI measures proposed by the ONS in their attempt to duck the issue of index bias has left us with nine official inflation measures. Take your pick! …without risking credibility As ever, there are one or two caveats. The textbook explanation of MGDP targets assumes that in order to steer the medium term inflation trend the authorities can assess the output gap and the trend in productive potential. However these are particularly difficult to gauge at the moment. The adoption of a target for MGDP growth would mean that this uncertainty was mirrored in the inflation trend – a disappointing economic growth trend would mean that inflation was consistently higher than expected for example. Also, to get MGDP we subtract the value of imports from the value of total expenditure. This leads to all sorts of statistical

Spring 2013

The standard argument for an inflation target is that inflation figures are understood by the general public and are available on a timely basis and never revised, unlike GDP figures. However, an intelligent lay person would surely understand why it was important to put economic growth on a par with inflation in present circumstances. Moreover, recent inflation target overshoots and debates about the way that inflation is measured have undermined the credibility of the inflation target. Ultimately, with employers now firmly in the driving seat when it comes to negotiating wages, it is not clear that public perceptions of inflation count for very much anyway these days. Perceptions are crucially important in bond and foreign exchange markets but these are surely sophisticated enough to accept the arguments for a change in the remit. In my view, apart from these minor caveats there would seem to be little reason to continue to target an indicator that is very hard to measure, let alone control.


The Unsung Heroes and Heroines – The Entrepreneurs By James Paton, 3rd Year Philosophy, Politics and Economics

T

he public always looks towards politicians and bureaucrats for the solutions to all economic problems – especially in times as grave as the present. However, the people we should be looking towards are not politicians. I argue that the capitalist or, a name with less negative connotations, the entrepreneur, is by far the most important person in society. These individuals are drivers of change, sources of growth and employment, and ultimately form the engine of wealth creation. This is not an exclusive group of people, but can be anyone willing to have a shot at running their own business – no matter how big or small.

Prices transmit dispersed knowledge throughout the economy and, through this mechanism, profit can be calculated. Chasing profit is the end of the entrepreneur and this is fundamental to the process of discovery and creative destruction that generates material wealth. Entrepreneurs are really the unsung heroes and heroines of society, and the public should admire, praise and look to them for inspiration. They will not help us out of the current mess unless we truly set them free from the burdens of government regulation and taxation. Entrepreneurs use prices, as knowledge is distributed across

the economy (See Hayek, 1945). Prices aggregate individuals’ preferences in particular markets, and changes in preferences lead to the fluctuation of the prices for goods and services. This is not to say that markets are ‘perfect’ and ‘purely’ efficient, as the imperfection of human action and markets is what makes markets work (Butler, 2010: pp. 48-49). Mistakes happen, which makes markets fallible, but prices guide the flow of resources to the production of that which consumers most want. With prices set by the market for inputs and outputs, entrepreneurs calculate expected profit from their investment. The individual who organizes the means of production wants to make money, and therefore seeks to maximise profit. He must make use of the very limited resources that he has, and use them to the best of his knowledge. There are two schools of thought on entrepreneurialism that can enlighten us on this issue. Kirzner saw entrepreneurship as a discovery process (Sobel, 2008): as individual firms are guided by profit, they try to shape individual preferences with new and innovative products that no one would ever have seen before. By calculating costs, potential revenues, and therefore expected profits by using market prices, they decide to supply the market with new services

or products. Through this process, many products have become crucial to our lives (such as mobile phones), but others fail. Entrepreneurs will adjust their behaviour in the light of their mistakes, communicated through the price and profit and loss mechanism, by quickly changing course . On the other hand, Schumpeter argued that entrepreneurship was creatively destructive (Schumpeter, 1961). In a competitive market environment, firms are always seeking profit: to do this they must be constantly innovating, making

If we want to set entrepreneurs free, and spur a new generation of ambitious individuals to build a wealthier, more innovative and dynamic society, we need to call on government to do less. better quality products or services for their consumers and always trying to achieve these goals at the lowest cost and price. Through new methods and the creation of new, better quality products at lower prices, entrepreneurs move on from old methods and products, to achieve their end of greater profit. In most cases, entrepreneurship

19


seems to me to be more like a discovery process. A small restaurant owner seeks to change the taste and test the preferences of the local community’s palate for example. However, there seems to be a bridge between the two theories – especially in consumable goods, where innovators are driving creative destruction. It seems that markets have a tangible discovery process. Take, for example, video cassettes: the destruction of videos through their replacement by DVDs, and then by digital files. It seems by simple analogy that we need discovery before destruction, but both are vitally important in the process of wealth creation.

argued, resources are best left with Second, intervention distorts the the people who are trying to make price mechanism because it crea profit, as they wish to make our ates false demand for goods and lives better on the condition that services. As prices rise because of they serve us with better products, government spending, this distorts services and at the lowest cost and the mechanism and pushes the prices. This is why first we need real reflections of market preferto cut taxes so entrepreneurs can ences to what they are. Resources keep what they earn in order to therefore tend to be misallocated spur them on to become even by government to what the market more entrepreneurial. Second, really demands. the state needs to cut spending so firms can allocate resources Third, where government does not to what the market demands, by compete, and does not have an in- letting the price mechanism work centive to use resources efficiently with less interference. And finally, (as it has the power of taxation we need to bring down the wall of to raise more funds), and is not bureaucracy that scares potential motivated by profit, where does entrepreneurs away from starting innovation come from? their own business. It raises costs, so profits are eaten away, deterIf we want to set entrepreneurs ring entry into the market and free, and spur a new generation of the expansion that is required for ambitious individuals to build a greater national growth, output wealthier, more innovative and dy- and employment. namic society, we need to call on References available online. government to do less. As I have

The importance of a free market and unfettered price mechanism is therefore founded upon the distribution of knowledge throughout society. When governments intervene in the market through spending and taxation, this distorts the mechanism that brings together fragmented knowledge. First, a government central planner cannot know where to put resources because market knowledge is dispersed, not centralised. There is no market and no rational pricing mechanism when government tries to provide a service through a central body (the socialist calculation problem –see von Mises, 1920), and it hence does not know where to allocate resources.

20

Spring 2013


Inequality - So What? By Dominic Falcão, 3rd Year Philosophy, Politics and Economics

At present, across OECD countries, the average income of the richest 10% of the population is about nine times that of the poorest 10%. While this ratio is much lower in the Nordic countries and in many continental European countries, it rises to around 14 to 1 in Israel, Turkey and the United States, to a high of 27 to 1 in Chile and Mexico. Growing Income Inequality in OECD Countries: What Drives it and How Can Policy Tackle it ? Forum, Paris, 2 May 2011 “[Efficiency can exist] even when some people are rolling in luxury and others are near starvation, as long as the starvers cannot be made better off without cutting into the pleasures of the rich. In short, a society can be Pareto optimal and still be perfectly disgusting” Amartya Sen, 1970, Collective Choice and Social Welfare What is central to a view of justice grounded in rational choice—that it does transmit natural inequalities into outcomes ... social institutions that failed to do this would not be rationally acceptable in failing to recognize the separateness of persons.’ Gauthier (1993b). ‘Uniting Separate Persons’, in Gauthier and Sugden (1993: 176–921). “So long as the gap is smaller, they’d rather have the poor poorer” Margaret Thatcher, Prime MInister’s Questions, November 22, 1990.

T

ypically, politicians stay away from the idea of really tackling inequality of outcome. And it is quite clear that this is because the first obstacle is persuading anyone that it is a problem. People are different, their activity in the world will bring them different fortunes. Our lives are not trains that can be regulated and made to advance at a steady, even pace (and even trains are seemingly troublesome to maintain in check). And even if they could be, the argument goes, our incomes would only stay even because no-one would earn anything at all - there would be no incentives, no differentiation between people. And there must be something true in these kinds of arguments: some people are more hard-working, do make bigger sacrifices to advance themselves and so the economy, their talents rarer, their productivity higher and so on. Moreover, a perfectly efficient market is comfortably the most effective way of converting these inequalities in talents into incentives, and

it is one that necessarily leads to inequality of outcome. What’s the problem? In considering why the market can appear both disgusting and perfectly suited to its task, it is important to note that the quotes from Sen and Gauthier above are founded on different premises. Their arguments do not overlap at the most important point: the fundamental goal of whatever

framework governs society. For Sen, if a society fails to ensure that people have the basic tools to lead a good life, there is something urgently wrong. For Gauthier, even if society seems “unfair”, interference for “moral” reasons needs explanation beyond moral intuitions: a society which acts in ways that cannot really be justified in terms of the self-interest of each individual (to put it crudely) acts in ways that are not justifiable at

21


all. If the purpose of a cooperative enterprise like “society” is mutual advantage, this must be the final judge. In between these two positions is the key gulf: the fact that there are some basic tools to lead a good life that it is not in everyone’s interests to provide. It is perhaps this conflict which makes equality such a vexed issue for politicians. If people need things, they need to justify any deprivation that fulfilling that need entails (how do we justify tax to those taxed if they don’t gain from it?). But there is not only a conflict at this lower end, there is a gap at the higher end of the scale too. Gauthier notes in Morals by Agreement that if an individual’s rare talents allow her to extract economic rent (income above the marginal produce that he contributes to society), the market is failing to allocate efficiently and the positions of some can thus be improved without making any worse off. Nevertheless, it is just too quick to take advantage of this shortfall and say: tax the money and give it to those who will not survive without it, or whose lives will be significantly improved by it. For instance, their lives may well significantly improve if they pull their socks up and work conscientiously. In which case, welfare actually makes everyone worse off: the rich are taxed and poor disincentivised from contributing to the economy. Righting inequality thus runs into underdetermination of outcomes and the problem of personal responsibility; the state doing things for people who would otherwise do things for themselves. Even where the market is inefficient, there is not a clear justification for interference.

very wide-ranging and persuasive. I will not attempt to deal with all of them here, but will merely attempt to (very briefly) survey some of them. One set of arguments focus on the relation between stability and inequality, as third year students of Applied Economics will be aware. An amateur historian might be tempted to offer this as a reason for the rise of welfarism post-WW2. Contemporarily for instance, at the time of the London riots, many cited inequality, resentment and “class” tension as causal reasons for that unrest. If it is the case that inequality causes instability, it is surely in everyone’s interests to take appropriate measures to alter this? And indeed, there is a significant body of literature gesticulating quite roughly in this direction (with all of the attendant difficulties that such gesticulation inevitably entails):

Despite this complexity, justifications for reducing inequality are

22

Spring 2013

“A large group of impoverished citizens, facing a small and very rich group of well-off individuals is likely to become dissatisfied with the existing socio-economic status quo and demand radical changes, so that mass violence and illegal seizure of power are more likely than when income distribution is more equitable.” 2 And it is just this sentiment that the Economist quotes Dominique Strauss-Kahn as expressing: “More unequal countries have worse social indicators, a poorer human-development record, and higher degrees of economic insecurity and anxiety.” 3 Alesina and Perotti, from whose work that quotation above is lifted, do not stop at the relation between inequality and instability, but try to show a connection between


inequality and growth by showing that instability threatens investment by reducing certainty about the future of the economy. Less growth, less mutual advantage: might this satisfy a Gauthierian proponent of firm inequality? The Spirit Level by two University of York lecturers provides a gamut of arguments: Inequality causes shorter, unhealthier and unhappier lives; it increases the rate of teenage pregnancy, violence, obesity, imprisonment and addiction; it destroys relationships between Inequality Inequality causes shorter, unhealthier and unhappier lives; it increases the rate of teenage pregnancy, violence, obesity, imprisonment and addiction; it destroys relationships between individuals born in the samesociety but into different classes; and its function as a driver of consumption depletes the planet’s resources.4 My personal feeling is that the best way of construing tax in terms of the self-interest of the taxed (if we must face Gauthier on his own premises) is to refer to Sen’s idea of a “perfectly disgusting” society: if my greater wealth comes at the cost of converting my society into something that is “perfectly disgusting” this is a nonmonetary incentive to accept tax of almost universal appeal. This is not revolutionary, it does not rest on questionable metaphysics; it simply gets at a good reason for acquiescing to some taxation and not fleeing to the Isle of Man. It is this idea which motivates unrest too: a highly unequal socioeconomic order which neglects the vulnerable is in a clear way repugnant, and being part of a repugnant society is something we ought to resist, with force if necessary.

But, Justice - So What? By Dan Howdon, 3rd Year PhD Economics

D

ominic’s article correctly, I think, identifies one unhelpful diversion in seeking to achieve greater equality of opportunity. I too think that there’s little to be gained in engaging with abstract theoretical discussion about what a ‘fair’ society constitutes, and what the pursuant implications for inequality are. I don’t, however, think the answer is to seek to justify greater equality of outcome to every member of our present society in terms of their

What do we talk about when we talk about inequality? From the weighty file of Bad Arguments in Favour of Good Ideas, Alesina and Perotti are quoted as stating that (I paraphrase only slightly) a substantial change in the social order would leave Phillip Green six feet under, whereas his Top Shop cleaners would live a relatively unchanged life. I’m not sure about the merits of this as an argument for greater equality

Photo: ktprior (http://www.flickr.com/photos/23743449@N00/480539103/sizes/l/in/photostream/)

own self-interest. If our aim is to equalise outcomes, it does not seem to me that this is best achieved by giving a veto, on movements from an initial distribution, to those who benefit most from this current distribution, and to encourage them to use this veto where their self-interest is harmed. There is one big, unasked, question that pervades all of these issues.

of outcome, except as the meekest justification for any taxation of the rich at all. If we adopt this position, we’re accepting an implicit objective of seeking to minimise the extent to which we reduce unequal outcomes within society, handed down by the ineffable logic of our existing economic relations, subject to the constraint of not provoking a full-blown revolution. In

References available online.

23


short, we accept the power relations within society as given, and we see if it’s possible to tinker at the edges – but only insofar as, in doing so, we further protect the essential character of these power relations themselves. This may be fine depending on your objectives, but seems to betray something of a paucity of ambition on the part of those apparently in favour of equality of outcome. The fundamental reason for which politicians do not tackle inequality of outcome is that they do not wish to do so. Not only is the virtue of meritocracy (a term born from a satirical warning about the idea itself), and its corresponding unequal rewards, an ‘unknown known’ within society1, but the benefits of inequality are, tautologically, unequally shared. That inequality of outcome is a problem to those at the bottom is obvious to those at the bottom: it simply isn’t experienced as a problem to those at the top. It is unlikely that any theory of fairness, no matter how

24

elegant, or any attempt to convince the rich of the self-interest of the forfeiting of their advantage, will affect this. As Aesop – according to some fiction, relevantly, an ex-slave – wrote: ‘When the hares addressed a public meeting and claimed that all should have

In short, we accept the power relations within society as given, and we see if it’s possible to tinker at the edges – but only insofar as, in doing so, we further protect the essential character of these power relations themselves. fair shares, the lions answered: “A good speech, Hairy-Feet, but it lacks claws and teeth such as we have”.’ Those who wish to push for equality of outcome should seek to increase the power of the weakest in society, rather than seeking to

Spring 2013

‘justify tax to those taxed if they don’t gain from it’, or ‘appeal to everyone’s interest’. I think this is in part why I increasingly become ill-tempered with appeals to ‘fairness’ or ‘justice’ as a political slogan, or a domain of enquiry in general. Nobody ever points out that, let alone questions whether, say, the victims of a murder are the victims of an injustice. Not only would this appear as hideously insensitive, but also as a category error, akin to questioning whether the colour pink can swim across the Atlantic Ocean. The best you’ll popularly get, when our own systems bring about deaths that could be delayed2, is a discussion of whether this is is ‘fair’. More important than the political sensitivity of what defines ‘fairness’, the determining of what falls under the umbrella of what may be discussed in terms of ‘fairness’ is itself a political act.


RD Laing, writing in 1967, noted that it was popularly taught that questions in this sphere of value judgement were considered to be ‘unanswerable, or untestable, or unverifiable, or not really questions at all’ and that ‘[m]eanwhile, Vietnam goes on’3. While Vietnam may have ended, it would be hard to dispute this today. So much writing about, and study of, fairness seems to be the only competitor to mainstream economics in the studious avoidance of the issue of power, and the results of it. As a working example, I’ve personally heard one of the many worthy people referenced in Dominic’s article publicly whinge, without providing any context or suggestion of understanding of

I don’t, however, think the answer is to seek to justify greater equality of outcome to every member of our present society in terms of their own selfinterest. why this is the case, about how rude and incompetent call-centre workers are. Thanks for your beautiful discussion of inequality of outcome: I too enjoy my comfortable academic position. To kick essential political questions of who gets what into the long grass growing resplendently in the abstract realm of fairness is, given the existing massively unequal power in society, to avoid answering these questions at all. Dominic ends his article by suggesting that ‘being part of a repugnant society is something we ought to resist, with force if necessary’. It’s hard to disagree. But what form would this force take? Is this something to take serious-

ly? Are we all off to Blue Moon Trading on Goodramgate tomorrow morning? If not, where are the claws and teeth of those pushing for greater equality? Where is the destruction in The Spirit Level? Comment is Free hand-wringing about fairness? In any economics you’ve ever read? I don’t know the answers to these questions, but it’s just as well that, before we react with horror to Dominic’s clear, explicit and unmistakable call for social revolution, we recognise

To kick essential political questions of who gets what into the long grass growing resplendently in the abstract realm of fairness is, given the existing massively unequal power in society, to avoid answering these questions at all. that it’s only a latent, fully cocked, force within society that maintains the existing social order. As Doug Henwood, author of a superb account of financial markets, re-

marks of his time as a secretary in a brokerage firm: ‘One morning, riding the elevator up to work, I noticed a cop standing next to me, a gun on his hip. I realized in an instant that all the sophisticated machinations that went on upstairs and around the whole Wall Street neighborhood rested ultimately on force.’4 As any honest economist would surely agree, and as the Athenians attest, without mystification, in the Melian Dialogue: ‘Right, as the world goes, is only in question between equals in power, while the strong do what they can and the weak suffer what they must’5. Those genuinely in favour of equalising outcomes can have endless discussions as to how best to justify theoretically, or in terms of everyone’s own rational self-interest, what they deem to be a decent or just society, but they would do well to take heed of this: God knows, their opponents have... References available online.

25


Use what you’ve got to get where you want At Ernst & Young we know your natural strengths can get you further, faster. We’ll help you identify, develop and use them to achieve your full potential. We have graduate and undergraduate opportunities available now in Advisory, Assurance, Corporate Finance and Tax.

Go from strength to strength www.ey.com/uk/careers

26

© Ernst & Young 2011. Ernst & Young is an equal opportunities employer and welcomes applications from all sections of the community. The UK firm Ernst & Young LLP is a limited liability partnership and a member firm of Ernst & Young Global Limited.

Spring 2013


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.