Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

Page 1

Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

7/18/09 11:16 AM

Grasping Reality with Both Hands The Semi-Daily Journal of Economist Brad DeLong: A Fair, Balanced, Reality-Based, and More than Two-Handed Look at the World J. Bradford DeLong, Department of Economics, U.C. Berkeley #3880, Berkeley, CA 94720-3880; 925 708 0467; delong@econ.berkeley.edu.

Support this weblog | About This Website | About Brad DeLong | This Weblog | Weblog RSS feed | Brad DeLong's Egregious Moderation | Order of the Shrill | Office Hours: Evans 601, by appointment, email delong@econ.berkeley.edu | Academic C.V. | John Yoo and the Torture Memo | Audio and Video Read the comment policy: no drive-bys, and if you bring information and humor you will be fine... A-List Banks & Insurance Is Your Bank Or Insurance Failing ? Discover the A List. Free Reports www.moneyandmarkets.com

Weblog Home Page Weblog Archives Econ 115: 20th Century Economic History Econ 211: Economic History Seminar Economics Should-Reads Political Economy Should-Reads Politics and Elections Should-Reads Hot on Google Blogsearch Hot on Google Brad DeLong's Egregious Moderation July 13, 2009

Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee... Greg Mankiw asks a question: Greg Mankiw's Blog: Modern macro even Paul Krugman will love: Lately, Paul Krugman has been dissing modern macroeconomics, mainly because many macroeconomists do not agree with his conclusions about fiscal policy. This new paper by Marty Eichenbaum, Larry Christiano, and Sergio Rebelo should, however, make Paul happy. They report large fiscal policy multipliers in a new Keynesian DSGE model when the economy is at the zero interest lower bound. http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/07/cracking-chistiano-eichenbaum-and-rebelos-big-multipliers-without-coffee.html

Page 1 of 5


Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

7/18/09 11:16 AM

large fiscal policy multipliers in a new Keynesian DSGE model when the economy is at the zero interest lower bound. An open question: How can the results in this paper be reconciled with results by John Cogan, Tobias Cwik, John Taylor, and Volker Wieland, who seem to perform a similar policy simulation in a similar model but reach a very different conclusion? Are there subtle differences in the models? Or subtle differences in the policy experiments? Or did one team simply make a mistake of some sort? Figuring out why these two prominent teams of researchers come to opposite conclusions about fiscal policy multipliers, and which conclusion is more applicable to actual policy, would be a good paper topic for an ambitious grad student. As I understand it, the big problem with Cogan, Cwik, Taylor, and Wieland is that there is nothing special going on at the zero nominal interest rate bound. In their model, a fiscal expansion (a) raises expected future inflation, which (b) creates expectations of future interest rate rises by the Federal Reserve to cool off that inflation, which (c) damps present spending, and so (d) shrinks the multiplier. Their model is a model of a small multiplier in an economy away from the zero nominal interest rate bound when central banks are targeting inflation. Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo, by contrast, have a model in which: a shock increases desired savings.... When the shock is small enough, the real interest rate falls and there is a modest decline in output. However, when the shock is large enough, the zero bound becomes binding.... The only force that can induce the fall in saving required to re-establish equilibrium is a large transitory fall in output. The fall in output must be very large because hitting the zero bound creates an economic meltdown. A fall in output lowers marginal cost and generates expected deflation which leads to a rise in the real interest rate. This increase in the real interest rate leads to a rise in desired savings which partially undoes the effect of the fall in output. As a consequence, the total fall in output required to reduce savings to zero is very large. This scenario captures the paradox of thrift originally emphasized by Keynes (1936).... The government spending multiplier is large when the zero bound is binding because an increase in government spending lowers desired national savings and shortcuts the meltdown created by the paradox of thrift... That said, I think that the CER multipliers are much too large to be applicable to our world today. If I understand CER completely (which I may not: the coffee has not yet hit the brain this morning), their Calvo pricing assumption creates a direct link between output Y and inflation π. Recall the flow -of-funds balance equation: S(Y, 0-π) = D + I(0-π) Savings S as an increasing function of income Y and of the real interest rate, which is the nominal interest rate 0 (we are at the lower bound) minus the inflation rate π, is equal to the government deficit D plus investment I which is a decreasing function of the real interest rate, which is the nominal interest rate 0 minus the inflation rate π. An increase in the deficit thus (a) directly increases saving S necessary to finance the deficit which requires a direct increase in Y. But this direct increase in Y then increases inflation π--there is less deflation. And less deflation means both less savings and more investment. So the direct effect increase in Y does not generate enough savings to close the gap in the flow-of-funds market: savings must increase by more--which requires that Y increase by even more. The government deficit thus genuinely "primes the pump" and the multiplier is very large. This channel is, I think, the channel pointed to by those who think that the New Deal had an enormous impact, as Roosevelt's deficits in combination with the increase in price rigidity produced by the NIRA and the breaking of deflationary expectations created by the abandonment of the gold standard diminished desired S. But I don't think we have big expectations of deflation right now. And I don't think fiscal policy moves right now are having a great deal of effect in reducing expected deflation. So I don't think the interaction of output gaps and deflation is playing a big role in boosting the multiplier right now...

http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/07/cracking-chistiano-eichenbaum-and-rebelos-big-multipliers-without-coffee.html

Page 2 of 5


Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

7/18/09 11:16 AM

I may well, however, assign CER next March when I hit the Great Depression week in Econ 210a as an argument for why Cary Brown's estimates of the fiscal policy effect of the New Deal are too low... And it is nice to see a model in which J. Bradford DeLong and Lawrence H. Summers (1986), "In Increased Price Flexibility Destabilizing?" American Economic Review makes a reappearence... rated 4.79 by you and 18 others [? ] You loved this post (

), you might also like:

links for 2009-07-16 (@this site) Washington Post Crashed-and-Burned Watch (@this site) 2 more recommended posts Âť Brad DeLong on July 13, 2009 at 08:45 AM in Economics, Economics: Fiscal Policy, Economics: Great Depression, Economics: History, Economics: Macro | Permalink TrackBack TrackBack URL for this entry: http://www.typepad.com/services/trackback/6a00e551f080038834011571fd7745970b Listed below are links to weblogs that reference Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...:

Comments You can follow this conversation by subscribing to the comment feed for this post. A more understandable narrative of the New Deal is that government deficits were spent more efficiently in 1933 that in 1930. Greater government output with increasing efficiency yields economic growth. Not having looked at government productivity data in the 30s (and we try not to measure it at all today!), I would speculate that the productivity of building transportation infrastructure by the New Deal increased continuously from 1932 to 1937. In 1937, transportation spending became inefficient as the government switched the economy to war trade. The debate about stimulus boils down to a debate about government productivity, and that determines inflation vs real growth at the current time. Posted by: Mattyoung | July 13, 2009 at 10:06 AM Fiscal expansion...inflation...creates expectations...large multiplier. Maybe you have alreadly answered my question Brad DeLong. Thank you very much. Posted by: Nancy Kirsch | July 13, 2009 at 11:00 AM Honest question from a student (mostly sans snark): "The only force that can induce the fall in saving required to re-establish equilibrium is a large transitory fall in output." How are we supposed to conceive of statements like this? Is it that everything returns to equilibrium and that savings, investment, whatever actually immediately (or very quickly, or however many periods the DSGE model tells us) race toward their "equilibrium" preserving levels? Or is this equilibrium conception one of those conveniences like "complete markets" or "Walrasian auctioneer" or "representative consumer" that we're supposed to understand are mathematically elegant constructions? I always assumed the latter, but sometimes I read things like the statement above and wonder. Not that I don't believe output falls in the situation described, but I don't believe it's falling "to re-establish equilibrium" or that it is falling to a somehow pre-determined (shock-determined) level. It just strikes me as epistemologically dangerous to think this way. It implies that there actually is some pre-determined (or post-dice roll determined, or however we are supposed to think the S part of DSGE) destination for an economy, http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/07/cracking-chistiano-eichenbaum-and-rebelos-big-multipliers-without-coffee.html

Page 3 of 5


Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

7/18/09 11:16 AM

pre-determined (or post-dice roll determined, or however we are supposed to think the S part of DSGE) destination for an economy, some trajectory guaranteed (until the S kicks in again). Policy "experiments" based on the models seem almost reasonable to me, but thought experiments that take the model's simplifications (needed for mathematical elegance and computability) to be actual features of the real world seem dangerous. I'm aware that I'm flirting with just being a semantics-arguing jerk. But I do think there is a real change in going from something like, "the model predicts this directional change given this change in the macroeconomy at approximately this proportion" to "the mechanism at work here is savings falling very quickly to re-establish required equilibrium with output which cannot get too low because the penalty is too high" as though there are referees or adjudicators forcing economic variables to stay in synch. I read the word "required" and get very, very uneasy. Posted by: jrc | July 13, 2009 at 11:19 AM No, that's absolutely right. No coffee with a big multiplier. Save it for later. Posted by: Nancy Kirsch | July 13, 2009 at 05:29 PM Suppose the model economy you have sketched were initially on the knife-edge between accelerating inflation and accelerating deflation, at zero interest rates. An *infinitesimally* small *temporary* change in fiscal policy should make the difference between the economy returning to normal (where monetary policy can take over again) vs. spiraling down to a *permanent* zero level of real output. I can't understand why the CER multiplier would not then be "doubly" infinite. I say "doubly" (speaking loosely) because the change in y in the numerator is both large and permanent while the change in G in the denominator is both infinitesimal and temporary. Posted by: Nick Rowe | July 14, 2009 at 03:04 AM Check spelling of Christiano in post title. That is all. Posted by: Paul | July 14, 2009 at 03:46 AM

Verify your Comment Previewing your Comment Posted by: | This is only a preview. Your comment has not yet been posted. Post

Edit

Your comment could not be posted. Error type: Your comment has been posted. Post another comment The letters and numbers you entered did not match the image. Please try again. As a final step before posting your comment, enter the letters and numbers you see in the image below. This prevents automated programs from posting comments. Having trouble reading this image? View an alternate. Continue

Me:

Economists:

Juicebox Mafia: Moral Philosophers:

http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/07/cracking-chistiano-eichenbaum-and-rebelos-big-multipliers-without-coffee.html

Page 4 of 5


Cracking Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Rebelo's Big Multipliers without Coffee...

Paul Krugman Mark Thoma Cowen and Tabarrok Chinn and Hamilton Brad Setser

Ezra Klein Matthew Yglesias Spencer Ackerman Dana Goldstein Dan Froomkin

7/18/09 11:16 AM

Philosophers: Hilzoy and Friends Crooked Timber of Humanity Mark Kleiman and Friends Eric Rauchway and Friends John Holbo and Friends

http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2009/07/cracking-chistiano-eichenbaum-and-rebelos-big-multipliers-without-coffee.html

Page 5 of 5


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.