Latest thinking
yo u g e t w h at yo u pa y f o r And when it comes to executive performance, how you pay for it makes a big difference.
WITHDRAWAL OF TRUST 27% of CFOs, treasurers and heads of mergers & acquisitions and debt capital market surveyed say they have lost trust in banks. Source: Dow Jones, 2009
12
Q3.2010
Gladwell recalls a famous experiment in the 1950’s in which the Harvard psychologist David McClelland observed a group of children playing a game that involved throwing a hoop over a pole. The children who took the greatest risk — standing so far from the pole that success was unlikely — also scored lowest in testing that measured their desire to succeed. McClelland concluded that those children were actually pursuing a psychologically protective strategy: the greater the risk, the less they could be blamed for failure. “That’s what companies are buying with their bloated CEO stock-option packages,” Gladwell writes, “gambles so wild that the gambler can lose without jeopardizing his standing in the corporate world.” That’s hard to refute. The past few years have made painfully clear what can happen when compensation for a chief executive is structured to encourage inordinate risk and short-term gains and offers no penalties for failure and, in fact, often rewards it. This has spawned a good deal of debate about whether executives are paid too much and for the wrong things. To the latter point, the Harvard Law School professors Lucian Bebchuk and Jesse Fried sounded an early warning in their 2004 book, Pay without Performance: The Unfulfilled Promise of Executive Compensation, assert-
ing that standard executive pay arrangements were leading executives to focus excessively and detrimentally on the short term. Since then, the authors have produced a steady stream of incisive work on the subject, including a recent (December 2009) paper, “Paying for Long-Term Performance,” that offers clear guidelines for a better approach to equity-based compensation. Bebchuk and Fried assert that a typical stock option plan imposes two types of costs on shareholders. First, when executives are free to unload a specified number of options that vest each year, the corporation must give them fresh equity to replenish their holdings. This dilutes the ownership of the public shareholders. Second, executives may take actions, both legal and illegal, that increase the stock price and their payout in the short run, even if those actions would destroy company value in the long run. The remedy? Executives should be blocked from cashing out their equity at the time of vesting. Although some firms do postpone executives’ cash-outs until their retirement dates, that approach has its own shortcomings; it could perversely induce the most successful executives to retire prematurely, and it still does nothing to discourage short-term thinking in the years preceding retirement. The solution that Bebchuk and Fried propose is to allow the unloading of equity only after a specified period of time has elapsed from the
HAl Mayforth
In a recent New Yorker article titled “The Sure Thing,” Malcolm Gladwell makes the case that successful entrepreneurs are not the high-wire acts that they are mythologized to be. Rather, they are highly risk-averse individuals who happen to be blessed with the instinct to spot opportunities others miss. In fact, seeking excessive risk doesn’t necessarily correlate with success at all.
T h e K o r n / F e r r y I n s tit u t e