Revenue Effects of the Global Minimum Tax

Page 1


RevenueEffectsoftheGlobalMinimumTaxUnderPillar

Two

InOctober2021,137countriesandjurisdictionsagreedtoimplementamajorreformoftheinternationalcorporatetaxsystem,i.e.,aglobalminimum tax of15%ontheprofitsoflargemultinationalcompanies.Thisarticlepresentssimulationsoftherevenueeffectsoftheglobalminimumtax.Twopossible scenariosareconsideredregardingwhocollectstheminimumtax:Thecountryinwhichtheheadquartersarelocatedbasedontheincomeinclusionrule (IIR)orthehostcountryofforeignaffiliatesaslaidoutunderthequalifieddomesticminimumtop-uptax(QDMTT).TheOrganizationforEconomic CooperationandDevelopment’s(OECD’s)tabulatedcountry-by-countryreport(CbCR)statisticsarecomplementedwithdatabyTørslov,Wier,and Zucman(2020).Basedonasampleofeighty-threeparentcountries,itisestimatedthatheadquarterscountriescouldcollectatotalrevenueofEUR179 billionglobally.TheEUMemberStatescouldreceiveEUR67billionfroma15%minimumtop-uptax.Carve-outs,provisionsthatdecreasethetaxbase forrealeconomicactivity,reducethepotentialtaxrevenuesbyapproximately14%to22%overtheentiresample.Underthecurrentagreement,the EuropeanUnioncanexpectatotaltaxrevenueofEUR55billionyearly.Theanalysisaccentuateshowthedistributionofrevenuesvariesdependingon whichcountryhastheprioritytocollect.UndertheIIRinwhichtheheadquarterscountrycollectsthetop-uptax,acountryreceivesmorerevenueswhenit hostsmoreheadquarteredmultinationals.Withqualifieddomestictop-uptaxesthatgivethehostcountryoftheforeignaffiliatetheprioritytocollectthe top-uptax,low-taxjurisdictionsthathaveattractedaffiliatesofmanymultinationalscouldbeamongthemainbeneficiariesofthereform.Static estimates thattakethedistributionofprofitsandtaxespaidasgiven,arepresented.Thereafterpossiblebehaviouraleffectsthatmayaffecttheestimatesarediscussed.

Keywords: Internationaltaxation,taxdeficit,globalminimumtax.

1INTRODUCTION

Globalizationhasaffordednewopportunitiesformultinational corporationstoreducetheirtax bills.Ascountriescompeteto attractinvestments,theymayhaveincentivestoreducetheir corporatetaxrates.Inaddition,multinationalcompaniescan recordearningsinjurisdictionswheretheycanminimizetheir taxbillwheretheyoftenemployasmallnumberofworkersand ownfewtangibleassetsbyshiftingpaperprofitstotaxhavens. Internationalcapitalmobility andprofitshiftinghaveledtoa substantialdeclineinthetaxeseffectivelypaidbymultinationalsglobally.Thisevolutionisunlikelytobesustainable, neitherpoliticallynoreconomically.

Multinationalshavepossibilitiestobooktheirprofitsinlowtaxcountries,butgovernments canchoosetotaxthoseoffshore profits.Since2019,theOrganizationforEconomic CooperationandDevelopment(OECD)hasbeenconsidering aminimumcorporatetaxrateformultinationalcompanies’ profits.InOctober2021,137countriesandjurisdictionsagreed

Notes

* EUTaxObservatory.Email:mona.barake@taxobservatory.eu.

** EUTaxObservatory.Email:paul-emmanuel.chouc@ip-paris.fr.

*** EUTaxObservatory&WorldInequalityLab.Email:theresa.neef@taxobservatory.eu.

ontheimplementationofa15%globalminimumtaxviathe OECD’sPillarTwoproposal.Thisagreementwasdetailedin theOECD’sModelRulesandtransposedintoadraftdirective bytheEuropeanCommissioninDecember2021.

Thisarticleestimateshowmuchcountriescouldcollect fromaglobalminimumtaxof15%onlargemultinationalcompanies’ profits.Twodifferentscenariosareconsidered.First,therevenuesarecollectedbythecountryin whichtheheadquartersofthemultinationalarelocated (inthefollowingreferredtoasheadquarterscountry) whichiscomparabletotheincomeinclusionrule(IIR) oftheOECD/G20agreement.Inasecondscenario,the hostcountrywheretheaffiliateofthemultinationalcompanyhasitstaxresidenceandprofitsarerecordedcollects theadditionaltaxrevenues.Thelattercasecorrespondsto thequalifieddomesticminimumtop-uptax(QDMTT) thatwasfirstintroducedintheOECD’sModelRulesof December2021underwhichtheQDMTThaspriority overtheIIR.Allresultsinthisstudyarefirst-round

**** UCBerkley&EUTaxObservatory.TheauthorswouldliketothanktheparticipantsintheWorldInequalityLabConference(2021)andtheHybridIntertax &Cideeff SeminaronPillarTwo(2022)fortheirhelpfulcommentsanddiscussions.TheyalsogratefullyacknowledgeGaspardRichardforexcellentresearchassistance.

effects,i.e.,beforebehaviouraladjustmentsofmultinationalsandtaxjurisdictionstothereform.

Thisstudyfindsthattheglobalrevenuepotentialofa 15%globalminimumtaxisapproximatelyEUR179billion.ThisnumberdecreasestoEUR139–165billionwhen substance-basedcarve-outsareintroducedanddependson theincomedeductionrates.FortheEU,therevenuesfrom PillarTwoareestimatedtobearoundEUR55billionunder theIIR.Thisamountstoalmost16%ofcorporatetax revenuesor4%ofthetotalhealthcareexpenditure.

Whetheritistheheadquarterscountrythatcollectsthetax revenues(undertheIIR)orthesourcecountry(underthe QDMTT)changesthegeographicaldistributionofrevenues amongcountries.Underthe ‘headquartersscenario’ ,acountry thathasmoreheadquarteredmultinationalsreceivesmore revenuesgeneratedbytheglobalminimumtaxespeciallyif themultinationalsareengagedinaggressivetaxplanning.In thesecondscenario,thehostcountrywheretheaffiliate operateswouldhavetheprioritytocollectthetop-uptax revenue.Inthiscontext,countriesthathaveattractedthe affiliatesoftax-aggressivemultinationalcompanieswould benefitthemostbeforebehaviouraladjustments.

Untilrecently,itwasdifficulttoestimatetherevenues fromaminimumtaxduetothelackofpubliclyavailable informationontheprofitsrecordedbycorporationsintax havens.1 Thishasbeguntochangeinrecentyearswiththe publicationoftwonewmacroeconomicdatasets:Thetabulationofmultinationalcompanies’ country-by-countryreports (CbCR)(publishedbytheOECD)andforeignaffiliatestatistics(FATS)(publishedbyEurostatintheEU,for instance).Thesenewdatagrantadditionalknowledge aboutthelocationofmultinationals’ profits(inparticular, howmuchisreportedintaxhavensglobally)andtoestimate theeffectivetaxratestowhichtheseprofitsaresubject.

Thisstudyaddstoabodyofliteraturethatestimatesthe revenuepotentialofaglobalminimumtax.Itiscloselyrelated toClausingetal.(2021)whoestimatehowmuchadditional revenuetheUnitedStatescouldcollectfromapplyinga21% minimumtaxontheundertaxedprofitsoftheirheadquartered multinationals.2 TheEconomicImpactAssessmentofthe OECD(2020)providesaglobalrevenueestimateofapproximatelyUSD150billion,asimilarapproximatecalculationas thatofthisarticle,withoutpresentingcountry-by-countryestimates.Devereuxetal.(2020)presentrevenuesestimatesfrom PillarTwofromtheIIR.Thisarticlecontributestothisdebate withcountry-by-countryrevenueestimatesoftheglobalminimumtaxagreedunderPillarTwo.Thisworkisprobablythe

firsttosimulaterevenuesofa minimumtaxbasedonthelatest agreementsofJulyandOctober2021aswellastheOECD’ s ModelRulesandtheEuropeanCommission’sdirectiveproposal ofDecember2021.Thisworkisalsobasedonthreereportsby Barakéetal.(2021).Theresultsarefurtherdiscussedinlightof thosestudiesintheresultssection.

Thisarticleisstructuredasfollows.Section2detailsthe PillarIIproposal,section3describestheunderlyingdata, andsection4continuesbyoutliningourmethodology. Section5providesrevenueestimatesforthescenariosoutlinedabove.Section6discussestheresultsconsideringprior studies,theincentiveeffectsofPillarTwo,theirpotential implicationsonrevenuegainestimates,andfurtherconsiderations.Section7concludes.Thisarticleissupplemented bytwoonlineappendices.OnlineAppendix13 provides moredetailsonmethodologyandrobustnesschecks. OnlineAppendix24 simulatesrevenueestimatesafterpossiblebehaviouraladjustmentsbymultinationalcompanies.

2THEPILLARTWOPROPOSAL

TheOECD/G20InclusiveFrameworkonBaseErosion andProfitShiftinghasproposedatwopillarsolutionto addressthetaxchallengesarisingfromthedigitalization oftheeconomy,i.e.,PillarOneandPillarTwo.The formerconsistsofthereallocationofresidualprofitsto jurisdictionsbasedonthemarketshareorenduserwhile thelatterintroducesaglobalminimumtax.Theirproposalseemstobeinitiallyintroducedasapackagetoaddress thedigitalizationoftheeconomy,however,eachiscurrentlybeingdiscussedseparately,especiallysincethe designofPillarOneisstillbeingdeveloped.

ThePillarTwoproposalconsistsofintroducingaminimumtop-uptaxof15%onundertaxedprofitsonacountryby-countrybasisineachjurisdictionwhereamultinationalis operating.UndertheIIR,theheadquarterscountryofa multinationalenterprise(MNE)willbeabletocollectrevenuesfromaffiliatesineachpartnercountrythathaveanETR lowerthan15%.WiththeintroductionoftheQDMTT,the priorityofcollectingtherevenuescanbeshiftedtothesource countryfromwheretheaffiliateoperates.Therearealsotwo rulesinthedesignofPillarTwo,i.e.,theunder-taxedpaymentrule(UTPR)andthesubjecttotaxrule(STTR).The UTPRfunctionsasabackupincasetheIRRisnotappliedby acountry,andtheSTTRappliesonsomeundertaxedpayments.Thisarticlewillfocusonthemainruleswhicharethe IRRandtheQDMTT.

Notes

1 Thisarticleconsidersthefollowingjurisdictionsastaxhavens:Andorra,Anguilla,AntiguaandBarbuda,Aruba,Bahamas,Bahrain,Barbados,Belgium,Belize,Bermuda, Bonaire,BritishVirginIslands,CaymanIslands,Curacao,Cyprus,Gibraltar,Grenada,Guernsey,HongKong,Ireland,Isleofman,Jersey,Lebanon, Liechtenstein, Luxembourg,Macau,Malta,MarshallIslands,Mauritius,Monaco,theNetherlands,Panama,PuertoRico,Seychelles,Singapore,SintMaarten,St.KittsandNevis,St.Lucia, StVincentandtheGrenadines,Switzerland,TurksandCaicos.ThiscorrespondstothelistestablishedbyThomasR.Tørsløv,LudvigS.Wier&GabrielZucman, The MissingProfitsofNations,NBERWorkingPaperSeries,No.24701(2018).

2 Seealso EmmanuelSaez&GabrielZucman, TheTriumphofInjustice – HowtheRichDodgeTaxesandHowtoMakeThemPay (NewYork,NY:WWNorton2020),Ch.6.

3 https://drive.google.com/file/d/13RBGWxUl0_sFKPnm3GOuaueU8Hlpyhp3/view

4 https://drive.google.com/file/d/1uzVAdAnNMhVGC0cW87rvqSVbPAKk9Hap/view

AnimportantaspectofthedesignofPillarTwoare carve-outs.Substance-basedcarve-outsallowforareductioninthetaxbaseinwhichthetop-uptaxwillapply.It willsubtract8%ofthecarryingvalueoftangibleassets and10%ofpayrolloremployeecompensationfromprofits.Inatransitionperiodoftenyears,theamountof excludedincomewillbedecliningtoreach5%oftangible assetsand5%ofpayroll.Theconceptbehindthesubstance-basedcarve-outsistoapplythetop-uptaxon affiliateswithnogenuineeconomicactivityandless extensivelyonaffiliateswitheconomicactivity.Thisarticlemodelsfirst-year(8%ofassetsand10%ofpayroll)and long-run(5%ofassets,5%ofpayroll)carve-outs.

TheseruleswillapplytoMNEswithanannualglobal turnoverofEUR750millionandabove.Governmententities,internationalorganizations,non-profitorganizations, pensionfunds,orinvestmentfundsthatareultimateparent entities(UPE)ofanMNEgrouporanyholdingvehicles usedbysuchentities,organizationsorfundsarenotsubject totheglobalanti-baseerosion(GloBE)modelrules.

Currently,thePillarTwoagreementhasnotyetbeen implementedinanycountry.IntheUnitedStates,the existenceofglobalintangiblelowtaxedincome(GILTI) wouldmeanthatitiseithergoingtobeadaptedinor goingtocoexistwithPillarTwo.Thelatterscenarioseems tobemoreprobable,andthetaxesfromtheGILTIwouldbe treatedascoveredtaxes.ThiswouldgivetheUnitedStates thepriorityforcollectingthetaxrevenuesofitsMNEswith respecttothesourcecountries.IntheEU,therehasbeenno progressontheproposeddirectiveimplementingtheglobal minimumtaxbecausethevetoofonemembercountryis sufficientforstoppingthedirective.

3DATA

OECD’sCbCRstatistics. Thebenchmarkdatasourceisthe tabulationsofmultinationalcorporations’ CbCRspublishedby theOECDforthefinancialyearsof2016and2017.This datasetprovidesaggregateinformationontheprofitsthat multinationalenterprisesrecordandthetaxesthattheypayin theirheadquarterscountryandinforeignjurisdictions. Currently,thirty-eightcountries providesuchinformationfor theirheadquarteredmultinationals.Allofthecomputationsare basedonthesubsampleofprofit-makingentitiesofthisdataset whichexcludestworeportingjurisdictions(PolandandLatvia). Thecalculationsusebothincomeyearstocomputeaverage effectivetaxratesandprofitsrecordedin2017toestimate potentialrevenue.5 TheOnlineAppendix,sectionB.1provides

someadditionalmethodologicalinsightsregardingthecomputationofaverageeffectivetaxrates,andFigureB.1.1plotsthe distributionofpre-taxprofitsacrosseffectivetaxratebrackets. Theavailabilityofcountry-by-countrydatamarksan importantmilestoneintheanalysisofglobalization.They arecurrentlytheonlysystematicsourceonthetaxeseffectivelypaidbymultinationalcompaniesineachofthecountriesfromwheretheyoperate.Thesedata,however,arestill intheirinfancyandsufferfromanumberoflimitations.In particular,inthefirstyearsofreporting,someprofitsare double-counted.Profitsassignedto ‘statelessentities’ (particularlysubstantialforUSmultinationals)areoftenalso countedelsewhere(eitherunderUSdomesticprofitsorina non-USjurisdiction).Thisissueisaddressedbyentirely omittingstatelessentities.Further,thedouble-countingof intra-firmdividendsinCbCRstatisticscaninflateprofits beforetaxandartificiallyreduceeffectivetaxratesasthese dividendsaregenerallysubjecttonoorlighttaxation(Horst andCuratolo,2020).WhenamultinationalfromCountryA ownsanaffiliateinCountryBthatitselfownsanaffiliatein CountryC,dividendspaidbyCtoBarenotconsideredpart ofB’srevenue,however,theyaresometimescountedaspart ofB’sprofit.Thisproblemappliesprimarilytodomestic observationsasintra-firmdividendsgenerallyaccruetothe headquarters.Thereisnowaytosystematicallyaddressthis issueatthisstage,butthedomesticpre-taxprofitsare adjustedtoexcludeintra-firmdividendswhenevertax administrationsprovidetherelevantinformation(thisis thecasefortheNetherlands,Sweden,andtheUnited Kingdom).6 Finally,possibleinconsistenciesforafewparent-partnerpairsindicatedbyexcessiveprofit-to-revenue marginsorlargefluctuationsinprofitsbetweenyearswere identified.7 Fortheseobservations,theproblematicobservationswerereplacedwithwhatisobservedforthesame parent-partnerpairintheotherpresumablynon-distorted financialyear,applyingnominalgrossdomesticproducts (GDP)growthratesforthesakeofcomparability.

Tørsløv,Wier,andZucman(2018,2019). Inthis article,theOECD’sCbCRdatawascomplementedwith estimatesbyTørsløv,Wier,andZucman(2018,2019)for theincomeyearsof2016and2017.Thedatasetdetails theamountofprofitthatmultinationalsrecordintax havens,brokendownbytheheadquarterscountry,the amountthatcompaniesreportthere,andtheireffective taxrate.TheseestimatesareobtainedbycombiningFATS fromwhichTørsløvetal.infertheamountofprofits reportedintaxhavensgloballyanddirectinvestment statisticsonanultimateownershipbasis.Fromthat,

Notes

5 Pleasenotethat2016and2017datawavesmightoverlap.The2016CbCRdataencompassesfiscalyearsthatbeganbetween01Jan.2016and01Jul.2016(and thusend between31Dec.2016and30Jun.2017).The2017datacomprisesfiscalyearsthatendbetween01Jan.2017and31Dec.2017(OECD, ImportantDisclaimerRegardingthe LimitationsoftheCountry-by-CountryReportStatists (2021),https://www.oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/anonymised-and-aggregated-cbcr-statistics-disclaimer.pdf).Thispartialoverlapshouldnotintroduceanybiassincethisdataisnotusedforregressionorotherpredictionmodels.Itmay,however,makethecomparisonoftheresultsforthetwofiscal yearsdifficult(see AppendixB.5forinstance).

6 Arule-of-thumbextrapolationofthisadjustmenttootherheadquarterscountriesisproposedintheOnlineAppendixB.4thataccompaniesthisstudy

7 ThisisthecasefortheBelgian2016and2017country-by-countrydataaswellasfortheSingaporean2017data.Formoredetails, see theOnlineAppendix.

theysubsequentlydeducetheheadquarterscountriesof theparentcompaniesthatrecordprofitsintaxhavens.8

Importantly,theresultingdatabaseisfreefromthe double-countingofforeignprofitsidentifiedbyBlouin &Robinson(2019)insomeofthestudiesthataimat estimatingthescaleofmultinationals’ profitshifting. Indeed,asameasureofcorporateprofitsinthedata maintainedbytheBureauofEconomicAnalysis(BEA), Tørsløvetal.donotusethe ‘netincome’ variablethat includesequityincomebutratherfocuson ‘profit-type return ’.Thelattervariableisobtainedfromtheformer withaseriesofadjustmentsthatnotablyexcludeequity incomeandisprovidedintheBEA’sValueAddedTables.

ThisdatasetismorecomprehensivethantheOECD’ s CbCRstatisticswhichallowsustoconsiderablyexpand theoriginalsampleofthirty-sixheadquarterscountriesto eighty-threejurisdictions.ForEUMemberStates,the databaseincludes,forinstance,estimatesoftheamount ofprofitsrecordedbyHungarianandPortuguesemultinationalcompaniesintaxhavens.Thisinformationis currentlyunavailableincountry-by-countrystatistics.

TheTørsløvetal.databaseandtheOECD’sCbCRstatistics aregenerallyconsistent.Bothindicatethatapproximately40% ofmultinationals’ foreignprofitsthatarerecordedoutsideof theirheadquarterslocationcountryarereportedintaxhavens. TheOECD’s2017CbCRstatisticsindicateatotalofUSD684 billionofprofitsaredocumentedintaxhavens;thisis40%of theamountofmultinationalprofitsallocatedinthesedata (USD1,716billion).Thisnumberisslightlylargerthanthat obtainedfromTørsløvetal.(2019)whofocusonprofits artificiallyshiftedtotaxhavensandestimatedashareof36%.

ORBIS. TheEuropeanCommission’sdirectiveproposalto implementPillarTwoinMemberStatesexpandstheminimumtaxliabilitybeyondmultinationalcompaniestopurely domesticenterpriseswithoutforeignsubsidiariesthatearn revenuesexceedingtheEUR750millionturnoverthreshold. Toestimaterevenuegainsfromthesepurelydomesticcompanies,theORBISdatabaseofBureauVanDijk(BvD)wasused. Itisbasedonpublicbusinessregistriesandcomprisesmicrodataoncompanies’ financialandoperatingmetricsaswellas ontheirdomesticandinternationalownershipstructure.9 One hundredandeightytwopurelydomesticcompaniesareidentifiedinEUMemberStatesoverthe2016–2021period.The identifiedfirmsarethosethathaveavailableconsolidated financialsandwhoseconsolidatedturnovermeetstheEUR

Notes

750millionthreshold.Duetomissingvalues,thetop-uptax liabilitiescanbecomputedforonly170ofthem. Auxiliarydatasources. Fourauxiliarydatasourcesare mobilizedinthisstudy.First,dataonthemeannominal monthlyearningsofemployeesfromtheInternational LabourOrganization(ILO,2021)toenricheachobservation withaproxyforannualpayrollexpenses.10 Second,statutory corporateincometaxratesusedtoimputemissingeffective taxratesaretakenfromKPMG’scorporatetaxratestable (2021).Third,exchangeratesaretakenfromthetimeseries oftheEuropeanCentralBank(2021).Fourth,theestimates areupgradedfromtheincomeyearof2017to2021basedon thenominalgrowthratesoftheEUandworldwideGDP observedintheWorldEconomicOutlookDatabase (InternationalMonetaryFund,October2021).

4METHODOLOGY

TheagreementontheglobalminimumtaxunderPillarTwo concretelyestablishedaminimumtaxrateof15%. MultinationalsthathaveaconsolidatedrevenueaboveEUR 750millioninatleasttwoofthelastfourfiscalyearsarein scope.Theglobalminimumtaxshouldapplytopretax profitsasreportedinthecompany’sfinancialaccountswith anumberofstandardizedadjustmentseliminatingcommon gapsbetweenaccountingandtaxableincome.Thistaxbase canbereducedbywhatisknownas substance-basedcarveouts thatamounttoapercentageofthecarryingvalueof tangibleassetsandpayrollexpensesthatthemultinational companyrecordsinthesubsidiarycountry.Overatransition periodoftenyears,carve-outrateswilldecreasefrom8%of thevalueoftangibleassetsand10%ofpayrolltoalong-run rateof5%onpayrollandtangibleassets.Thisprovision reducesthetop-uptaxliabilityincountrieswithsubstantial activitywhilethefulltop-uptaxof15%appliesincountries withnogenuineeconomicactivity.Thetaxliabilitywillbe globallydeterminedforeachmultinationalcompany. However,thedatabasethatisusedonlyprovidesaggregate informationattheheadquarterscountryptosubsidiary jurisdictionjlevel.Thetaxbaseisthuscomputedhere underlong-runcarve-outratesasfollows:

TaxBasepj =Profitspj – 5%(Payrollpj +TangibleAssetspj) [1]

Forwhich Profitspj indicatestheprofitsbeforetaxofthe subsidiariesofmultinationalsheadquarteredincountryp

8 Ingeneral,foreignaffiliatestatisticscontainsimilarinformationasthatofcountry-by-countryreportstatistics.AnotabledifferencebetweenbothdatasourcesisthatCbCR dataonlycomprisemultinationalenterpriseswithaglobalturnoverofEUR750millionandmorewhileforeignaffiliatestatisticsdonotapplysucha threshold.

9 Theempiricalliteratureoncorporatetaxplanninghasextensivelyusedthisdatabase,includingstudiesontherevenuepotentialoftheglobalminimumtax(MichaelP. Devereux,FrançoisBares,SarahClifford,JudithFreedman,IremGüçeri,MartinMcCarthy,MartinSimmler&JohnVella, TheOECDGlobalAnti-BaseErosionProposal (OxfordUniversityCentreforBusinessTaxation2020)),OECD, TaxChallengesArisingfromDigitalisation – EconomicImpactAssessment:InclusiveFrameworkonBEPS,OECD/ G20BaseErosionandProfitShiftingProject(Paris:OECDPublishing2020).

10 Sinceemployeesofmultinationalcompaniesarelikelytoearnabove-averagewages,thefinalpayrollestimatesareupgradedbya20%premium.Thisupgradefactorcanbecompared withthemultinationalwagepremiumestimatesidentifiedorgatheredbyFredrikHeyman,FredrikSjöholm&PatrikTingvall, IsThereReallyaForeignOwnershipWagePremium? EvidencefromMatchedEmployer-EmployeeData,73(2)J.Int’lEcon.355–376(2007),RitaAlmeida, TheLaborMarketEffectsofForeignOwnedFirms,72(1)J.Int’lEcon.75–96(2007),or KhadijaVanderStraaten,NiccolòPisani&AnsKolk, UnravelingtheMNEWagePremium,JournalofInternationalBusinessStudies(2020),SSRN,https://ssrn.com/abstract=3717151. Forinstance,thelatterfindawagepremiumassociatedwithworkingforamultinationalcompanyof32%usingmicro-leveldatafromover40,000employeesinthirteencountries.As theycontrolforvariablessuchaseducationorfirmsize,thisestimatemayevenbealowerboundforthe naïve upgradefactorthatisapplied.

operatinginpartnerjurisdictionj;similarly, Payrollpj denotes thepayrollexpensesofthosesubsidiariesinpartnerjurisdictionj,and TangibleAssetspj indicatesthecarryingvalueoftheir tangibleassets.Pretaxprofitsandthenumberofemployees aredrawndirectlyfromtheOECD’sCbCRdata.Tangible assetsarealsoavailable,however,thevariablecaninclude inventories(OECD,2020)thatwerefactoredoutfromthe tangibleassetscomponentofcarve-outsinpreviousversions oftherules.Noadjustmenthasbeenmade,butfurther guidanceonthisaspectmightmakeacorrectionnecessary. Inthatcase,theresultsdisplayedbelowwouldoverestimate theeffectofthesubstance-basedincomeexclusionand(toa lesserextent)understaterevenuegains.Forpayrollexpenses, theILO’smeanearningsdataweremobilized(see section2). SectionB.2oftheOnlineAppendixprovidesadditional practicalindicationsregarding theintegrationofsubstancebasedcarve-outs,andadiscussionregardingtheinclusionof inventoriesintheirtangibleassetscomponentinSectionB.6. IntheagreementsofJulyandOctober2021,theIIRisthe primarilytoolusedforrevenuecollection.Itallowstheheadquarterscountryofamultinationaltoapplytheminimum top-uptaxwhenitsaffiliatesencounteraneffectivetaxrate below15%.ThemodelrulesofDecember2021introduceda newcollectionmechanism.UndertheQDMTT,hostjurisdictions,i.e.,jurisdictionswheremultinationals’ foreignsubsidiariesrecord(undertaxed)profits,havethepriorityto collectthetaxrevenuesoverheadquarterscountries.

Inthesimulations,thefocusisontheIIRandtheQDMTT, andotheraspectsofthemodelrulesareabstracted:First,from theSTTRthatwouldhavepriorityovertheIIRandQDMTT; second,fromtheinteractionwithPillarOne;andthird,from thecollectionofrevenuesthroughtheUTPR.Multinationals’ andtaxjurisdictions’ behaviouralresponsesarealsoabstracted. Someofthebehaviouraleffectsthatcouldinfluencetherevenue gainsandtheirdistributionarediscussedinsection5.

Intheheadquartersscenario,i.e.,underthefullimplementationoftheIIR,taxrevenuesthatcanbecollectedby theheadquarterscountrypareestimatedasfollows:

Revenuep = ∑j J (15% – ETRpj)×TaxBasepj [2]

TaxBasepj isgivenbyequation(1)forthesubsidiariesof multinationalsheadquarteredinparentcountrypinpartner jurisdictionj; ETRpj istheaverageeffectivetaxratethat thosesubsidiariesencounter.11 Intheheadquartersscenario,

Notes

headquarterscountriesfullycollecttheadditionalrevenues fromtheglobalminimumtaxwhilesubsidiarycountriesdo notobtainanyextrarevenue.FollowingtheEuropean Commission’sdirectiveproposal,EUMemberStatesare assumedtoimposethetop-uptaxnotonlyonforeignlowtaxedprofitsbutalsoonthoserecordeddomestically.Stated otherwise,Equation[2]includescountrypintherighthand-sidesumifandonlyifpisanEUMemberState.

UnderthefullimplementationoftheQDMTT,partner jurisdictionsjwheresubsidiariesarelocatedwouldcollect thefullrevenuesfromtheminimumtax:

Revenuej = ∑p P (15% – ETRpj)×TaxBasepj [3]

Thenextsectionprovidesrevenueestimatesfortheimplementationofeachofthetwoscenariosoutlinedin Equations(2)and(3).Itislikely,however,thatsome butnotallhostcountrieswillimplementtheQDMTT whichwouldleadtoahybridcase.

CbCRstatisticsprovidedetailedinformationonprofits, taxespaidaswellasthenumberofemployeesandtheamount oftangibleassetsthatthesubsidiariesofmultinationalsheadquarteredincountryprecordin partnerjurisdictionj.Tørsløv etal.(2018,2019)onlyprovidesdataontheprofitsofthe subsidiariesofmultinationalsheadquarteredincountryp operatingintaxhavensandintheheadquarterscountry.To computerevenueestimatesasdetailedabove,severalassumptionshavebeenmade.First,a10% effectivetaxrateisassumed inallofthetaxhavens.Thisisaratherconservativeassumption.UsingthesametaxhavenclassificationasinTørsløv, Wier,andZucman(2018,2019),anaverageETRintax havensofapproximately5%isfound.12 Second,theminimum taxrevenuefromnon-havenjurisdictionsisimputedby assumingthattheratioofrevenuegainsfromtaxhavensto non-taxhavensobservedinCbCRdataappliestotheextended sample.Fordetailsontheimputations, see theOnline Appendix(AppendixB.3).

Duetothestructureanddetailoftheunderlyingdata,the estimatesmightleadtounder-andoverestimatingadditionalrevenues.Ontheonehand,thetabulatedOECD CbCRdatausedinthisstudydeliversdownward-biased revenueestimatesbecauseofheterogeneityineffectivetax rateswithineachcountrypair.Entitiespaying highcorporateincometaxesmaycompensateforthosein thescopeoftheminimumtaxwithinajurisdiction.13

11 Theeffectivetaxratewillbecalculatedonacountry-by-countrybasis.Thisavoidsundertaxedprofitsbeingblendedwithtaxespaidinhightaxcountries.Incometaxespaid aredividedbypretaxprofitsforeachparent-partnerjurisdictionpairtocomputetheeffectivetaxrates.Tostabilizeeffectivetaxrates,averagetaxratesoverthetwoavailable incomeyearsof2016and2017areused:

Withtheavailabledata,someadjustmentsincludedinthemodelrulesdefinitionof ‘adjustedcoveredtaxes’ cannotbemade,e.g.,noneoftheincometaxvariablesin country-by-countryreportstatisticsincludedeferredtaxesorcontrolledforeigncompany(CFC)taxpaymentscannotbeaccountedfor.

12 ThisETRof4.8%isaprofit-weightedaveragebasedon271parent-partnerobservationswherethepartnerisataxhavenfortheincomeyearof2017.TheETRsareaverage across2016and2017inordertostabilizethem.Outliersarewinsorized.Theunweightedaverageamountstoapproximately7%.Thus,theassumptionof 10%will probablyresultinalower-boundestimateforrevenuesfromtaxhavensinthedatabasebyTørsløv,Wier,andZucman(2018,2019).

13 Forexample,imaginethathalfofFrenchmultinationalshaveaneffectivetaxrateof20%(euro-weighted)inapartnercountry,andtheothershaveaneffectivetaxrateof 10%inthesamecountry.TheaverageeffectivetaxratereportedintabulatedstatisticsforFrenchmultinationalsinthiscountryis15%and,thus,theestimatedtop-uptax liabilityis0.Inreality,thetruerevenuegainispositivesincethemultinationalswithaless-than-15%effectivetaxratereportundertaxedprofits.

Ontheotherhand,therevenuegainestimatesin thisstudycanbebiasedupwardsviafivemain mechanisms.

First,thedouble-countingofintra-firmdividends inCbCRstatisticscaninflateprofitsbeforetaxand artificiallyreduceeffect ivetaxratesasdiscussed above.Thispotentialbiasiscorrectedwheneverthe requiredinformationisavailable( see section2). Second,therevenueeffectsofPillarOnearenot considered;however,theOECD ’ sEconomicImpact Assessment(2020)findsonlymarginaleffectsrelated toitsapplication.Third,newlymultinationalcompaniesforwhichthemodelrulesapplyexemptions, arenotdistinguishedinthedata.Further,the de minimis exclusioncanonlybepartiallymodeled. 14 Fourth,whilePillarTwowillonlyapplytomultinationalcompanieswithaglobalturnoverofEUR 750millionandabove,Tørsløvetal.(2018,2019) dataarenotrestrictedtomeetthiscriterion.This mightleadtotheinclusionofrevenuesfromsmaller companiesnotsubjecttoPillarTwo.Five,inthe ‘ headquartersscenario ’ (Equation2),thespecific treatmentofpartiallyownedentitiesundertheIIR aredisregarded. 15 Thefulltop-uptaxamountis systematicallyattributedtotheheadquarterslocation countryregardlessoftheownershipstructureofthe multinationalcompanies.Thissimplificationis imposedbytheaggregateCbCRdatathatismobilized.Itseffectontheestimatedaggregaterevenue gainsdependsonwhetherthetop-uptaxamountthat isattributabletominorityshareholdersandremains outsidethescopeoftheIIRiscollectedthroughthe UTPR( see Noked(2022)forafurtherdiscussion).If so,thecomputationsinthisstudydonotoverestimatethetotalrevenuestobecollectedfrompartially ownedentitiesbutcovert heeffectofboththeIIR andtheUTPR.Ifthisisnotthecase,thenthe aggregaterevenuegainestimatesforthefirstscenario includetop-uptaxesthatwillnotbecollected.The effectofthissimplificationshouldbelimited.The orderofmagnitudeoftheestimatesinthisstudy shouldnotbesystematicallybiasedineitherdirectionconsideringallofthosefactorsandtheirsignificancefortheresultingrevenueestimates.

Notes

5RESULTS

5.1 HeadquartersScenario:Full ImplementationoftheIIR

Therevenueeffectsofa15%globalminimumtaxarefirst presentedwithandwithoutcarve-outsascollectedbyheadquarterscountries.ThefullimplementationoftheIIR wouldentailthattheheadquarterscountryofthemultinationalcompanycollectsthedifferencewhentheaffiliateof amultinationalhasaneffectivetaxrateoflessthan15%. TherevenuesareexpressedinEURbillionasashareof projectedcorporatetaxrevenuesin2021(absentachange inthetaxlaw)andasashareofcurrenthealthspending.

ThefindingssuggestthattheEUwouldcollectapproximatelyEUR67billionfroma15%minimumtaxwithout carve-outs.Forcomparison,thisamountrepresentsaround 19%ofthecorporatetaxrevenuescurrentlyraisedintheEU and5%ofcurrenthealthcareexpenditures.16 Substantialrevenuegainsarealsoexpectedfortheotherheadquarters countriescoveredintheOECD ’ scountry-by-country statistics.UndertheIIR,countriesthatheadquarters manylargeprofit-shiftingMNEsareexpectedtodraw thelargestrevenuegains.ItisfoundthattheUnited Statesisbyfarthecountrythatwouldbenefitthemost underthisscenariowithestimatedrevenuesofabout EUR58billion.WesternEuro peancountriesalsoappear amongtheprimarybeneficiariesoftheglobalminimum tax.Inthisgroup,German ywouldcollectalmostEUR 13billionofadditionalrevenues,SpainaboutEUR5 billion,FranceEUR4billion,andItalyapproximately EUR3billion.Othernon-EUcountriesthatwouldcollectsignificanttaxdeficitrevenuesareCanada(EUR9 billion),Japan(EUR6billion),andtheUnitedKingdom (EUR7billion).Additionally,somelower-taxjurisdictionsthathaveattractedanumberofheadquartersover thelastdecadesareattributedsubstantialrevenuesfrom theminimumtax.Thisisthecaseinparticularfor Irelandcollectingmo rethanEUR12billion, LuxembourgreceivingEUR6billion,andSwitzerland withEUR3.5billionofadditionalrevenue.Poland wouldobtainmostofitsrevenuegains,almostEUR4 billion,fromtheundertaxedp rofitsbookeddomestically byitsmultinationals,asdiscussedinmoredetailbelow.

14 AccordingtoArt.5.5oftheOECD’sModelRules,ifanin-scopemultinationalcompanyreportssufficientlylowrevenueandprofitsinaspecificjurisdiction,itwouldbefreefromany top-up taxrelatedtothecorrespondingincome.Moreprecisely,fortheexemption toapply,theconstituententitymustrecordanaveragerevenuebelowEUR10millionandaverageprofitslessthan EUR1millionwiththeaveragebeingcomputedoverthelastthreeincomeyears.Astheyonlyprovideinformationatthecountrypairlevelandnotatthelevelofconstituententities,thedata arenotgranularenoughtoincorporatethe deminimis exclusion.Thetop-uptaxesarebroughttozeroforallofthecountrypairsthatdisplayaggregaterevenueandprofitsbelowtheirrespective threshold,however,thisaffectstheresultsonlymarginallyandthetabulationofcountry-by-countryreportstatisticsimpliesthattheimpactof theexclusionisunderestimated.

15 Considertheforeignaffiliateofamultinationalcompanywithataxbase(profitsbeforetaxnetofsubstance-basedcarve-outs)ofUSD1,000andaneffectivetaxrateof10%. Thetotalamountoftop-uptaxassociatedwithlow-taxedentityistherefore5%*USD1,000=USD50.Iftheaffiliateisfullyownedbytheheadofthemultinational group,theentireamountiscollectedbytheheadquarterscountryundertheIIR.However,ifthegroupheadonlyowns80%oftheshares,thetop-uptaxcollectedbythe headquarterscountrywillonlybe80%*USD50=USD40.The80%factorwouldcorrespondtothe ‘inclusionratio’ mentionedinthemodelrules.Theimplicationsof thisscenarioarefurtherdiscussedintheOnlineAppendixwithmorecontextandatentativeassessmentofthescaleoftheoverestimationinduced(see s.D).

16 TheOnlineAppendix,TableA.3.1presentsthebenchmarkrevenuegainestimatesexpressedasashareofthecorporateincometaxrevenuescurrentlycollectedandthe currenthealthcareexpenditures.

ParentCountryNoCarve-Out

Year1:8%ofTangibleAssets, 10%ofPayroll

AfterYear10:5%of TangibleAssets&Payroll

Austria3.11.72.3

Belgium4.03.03.4

Cyprus0.20.20.2

CzechRepublic0.10.00.1

Denmark1.81.41.6

Estonia0.10.10.1

Finland1.51.21.3

France4.03.33.6

Germany13.38.010.1

Greece2.21.51.7

Hungary0.60.30.4

Ireland12.611.111.7

Italy3.12.42.7

Latvia0.20.10.1

Luxembourg5.94.65.1

Malta0.10.10.1

Netherlands2.41.82.0

Poland3.82.02.7

Portugal0.10.00.0

Romania0.10.00.1

Slovakia0.00.00.0

Slovenia0.00.00.0

Spain5.32.63.6

Sweden2.72.02.3

EUtotal67.147.455.2

Changein%-29.3%-17.8%

Argentina0.10.10.1

Australia1.81.41.6

Bermuda1.31.11.2

Brazil1.51.31.4

ParentCountryNoCarve-Out

Year1:8%ofTangibleAssets, 10%ofPayroll

AfterYear10:5%of TangibleAssets&Payroll

Canada9.16.77.6

Chile0.00.00.0

China6.23.44.4

India0.60.40.4

Indonesia0.10.10.1

IsleofMan0.10.10.1

Japan6.04.85.2

Singapore0.70.50.6 SouthAfrica3.02.42.6 Switzerland3.53.03.2

UnitedKingdom7.05.15.9 UnitedStates58.152.154.4 OECD162.6127.8141.2

Changein%-21.4%-13.2% Fullsample179.1139.2154.5

Changein%-22.3%-13.7%

Thesubstance-basedincomeexclusionincludedinthe internationalagreementsofJulyandOctober2021andin theOECD’sModelRulessubstantiallyreducespotentialrevenues,asshowninTable1.Inatransitionperiodoftenyears, carve-outswilldecreasefrom8%ofthecarryingvalueof tangibleassetsand10%ofpayrollinthefirstyeartoalongrun,constantrateof5%onpayrollandassets.IntheEU,with thecarve-outratesofthefirstyearofimplementation,

estimatedrevenuegainsarereducedbyapproximately29% fromEUR67to47billion.Withfirst-yearcarve-outs,the estimateofEUR139billion(in2021)ofglobalrevenuegains fromtheminimumtaxisbroadlyinaccordancewiththeUSD 150billion(oraboutEUR127billion)estimateprovidedby theOECD.17 Withthelong-runcarve-outratesof5%for bothassetsandpayroll,revenuegainswoulddecreasefromthe initialEUR67billiontoEUR55billionintheEU.Thus,EU

Thistablepresentestimationsofrevenuegainsundertheheadquartersscenario.WhentheaffiliateofanMNEhasanETRbelow15%,theheadquarters countryoftheMNEcollectsthedifference.Resultsarepresentedwithoutcarve-outswithfirstyearcarve-outs(8%oftangibleassetsand10%ofpayroll) andlong-runcarve-outs(5%oftangibleassetsandpayroll).Thesampleisrestrictedtocountrieswithavailabledata. Notes

17 TheECB sUSD-EURmarketexchangeratefor2021of1.18274isusedforthisstudy.AccordingtothepressreleasethataccompaniedthejointstatementofOct.2021, theglobal minimumtaxagreement[ ]will see countriescollectaroundUSD150billioninnewrevenuesannually’.However,themethodologiesusedtoobtaintheresultsandthisfigure cannotbecomparedasthecontentoftheproposalhaschangedsubstantiallysincethereleaseoftheOECD sEconomicImpactAssessmentinOct.2020.

countrieswouldincreasetheirrevenuesbyalmostEUR55 billionor16%ofcurrentcorporateincometaxrevenueunder thebenchmarkestimationinthisstudy,a15%minimumtax rate,andlong-runcarve-outs.18

Theestimatedtaxrevenuesreflecthowmuchheadquarterscountriescancollectfromtheirmultinationals’ foreign affiliatesbutalsofromEUMemberStates’ domesticaffiliates.FortheEU,themajorityofadditionaltaxrevenuesare collectedfromforeignprofits.However,asubstantialpart oftotalrevenues,between20%and40%,comesfrom revenuesfromtheundertaxedprofitsofmultinationalcompaniesintheheadquarterscountry(forthe15%minimum taxwithlong-runcarve-outratesof5%).Thishighshareof domesticrevenuearisesfromasmallnumberofcountries includingGermany,Ireland,Luxembourg,andPoland. Furthercountry-specificreasonsfortheirhighdomestic revenuesarediscussedinAppendixB.4.Therevenue gainsfromEUmultinationals’ foreignaffiliatescanbe furtherbrokendownintotaxhavensandnon-havensfrom whichtheEUwouldgainaboutEUR11billion,andnonhavenpartnerjurisdictionswouldacquirealmostEUR23 billionofatotalofEUR55billionunderthebenchmark estimation,i.e.,approximately40%oftotalrevenue.19 The maincontributingjurisdictionstothesenon-havenrevenuesareAustraliawithEUR2.7billion,theUnited KingdomwithEUR7.7billion,theUnitedStateswith EUR4.6billionaswellassomeblendedjurisdictionssuch as ‘OtherEurope’ withEUR5.4billionand ‘Other Americas’ withEUR4.5billion.Foradetailedbreakdown byjurisdictiontype, see TableA.1.1intheOnline Appendix.

Severalcountrieshaveexpressedinterestinamoreambitiousglobalminimumtax.Thefindingssuggestthatrevenuesincreasemorethanproportionallywithanincreasein theminimumtaxrate.Witha21%minimumrate,the EuropeanUnionwouldhavecollectedapproximatelyEUR 118billionin2021(asopposedtoEUR55billionwitha 15%minimumtaxrate).Movingfrom21%to25%would increasetherevenuepotentialuptoEUR166billion.This non-linearitywasidentifiedbyDevereuxetal.(2020)in theirempiricalfindings.Astheyexplain,twoconcomitant effectsarerelevantwhentheminimumeffectivetaxrateis raised:Thetop-uptaxrateappliedtoprofitsalreadyin scopeincreases,andmoreprofitsareconsideredasundertaxedandtherebyfallinthescopeoftheglobalminimum tax.TableA.2.1intheOnlineAppendixdemonstrateshow varyingminimumtaxrateswouldaffecttherevenuegains.

TheOnlineAppendixoffersfurtherresultswithdifferentadjustmentstothebenchmarkestimatesinthisstudy. Specifically,inAppendixB.4theeffectofpossibledouble-countingofintra-firmdividendsonthestudy’sestimatesisdiscussed.Usingasimplerule-of-thumb adjustmentbasedoncountriesthatprovidecorrected profitaggregates,alloftheheadquarterscountryprofits uniformlydecreasebyabout40%.Withthisadjustment, theEuropeanUnionwouldstillgainapproximatelyEUR 42billionperyearfroma15%minimumtaxwith5% carve-outs.Particularly,Germanywouldhalfitsoverall revenuefromEUR10billiontoEUR5billionperyear. Theresultingrevenueestimatescanbeconsideredas lowerboundestimates.20

5.2 Headquartersv.SubsidiaryCountry Collection

ThemodelrulesofDecember2021introducedanew revenuecollectionmechanismwithQDMTTs.Under thelatestrules,thehostcountrywherethemultinational hasanundertaxedaffiliatewouldhavethepriorityto collectthePillarTwominimumtax.Therefore,acountry wouldcollectrevenuesifithasasubstantialnumberof affiliatestaxedataneffectiveratebelow15%.

Table2comparestherevenuescollectedundertheIIR (headquarterscountrycollection)withtherevenuesunder theQDMTT(subsidiarycountrycollects).Low-taxcountriesthathaveattractedmultinationalaffiliateswould gainthemostundertheQMDTT(beforebehavioural adjustments).LuxembourgcollectingaboutEUR12.5 billionandtheNetherlandsapproximatelyEUR14billionwouldaccountforalmosthalfofthetotalEUrevenues.Bermuda(EUR8billion),theCaymanIslands(EUR 11billion),PuertoRico(EUR5billion),Singapore(EUR 8billion),Switzerland(EUR8billion),andtheUnited Kingdom(EUR7billion)areamongthecountriesthat wouldcollectmosttaxrevenuesfromQDMTTs. However,itshouldbenotedthatthedistributionof revenuegainsestimatedinthissecondscenarioisprobablynotrobusttocompanies’ andjurisdictions’ responses totheminimumtax.Typically,asthe(closeto)15%floor reducesprofitshiftingincentives,thehighestimatefor theCaymanIslandsmightbeoverestimatedandshouldbe carefullyinterpreted.Potentialbehaviouralresponsesare reviewed,andtheirexpectedeffectsonrevenuegainsare analysedinsection5.

Notes

18 Allfollowingdiscussionsinthissubsectionarebasedonthisbenchmarkscenario.

19 Inthecategoryofnon-taxhavens,jurisdictionsareincludedthatarenotdeemedtaxhavensandalsoblendedjurisdictionssince,inCbCRdata,somepartnerjurisdictionsare onlyspecifiedas ‘OtherEurope’ or ‘OtherAmericas’.Additionally,severalparentjurisdictionsonlyhaveacontinentalsplitintoprofitsthatarerecordedandtaxespaidin Africa,theAmericas,Europe,etc.

20 See theOnlineAppendixforfurthercountryestimates.Thisisarule-of-thumbcorrectionthatcanbeconsideredasalowerbound.Sincetheguidelineswereambiguousin theinitialyearsofCbCreporting,somecountriesmightalreadyhaveexcludedintra-firmdividendswhileothershavenot.Itisassumedthatallcountriesdouble-count intra-firmdividendsintheadjustmentinthisstudy.

Incontrast,revenuescollectedbytheUnitedStateswould significantlyfallfromEUR54billiontoEUR3billion whenmovingfromtheheadquarterscollectiontothehost countrycollection.TheUnitedStatesindeedhoststheheadquartersofmanylargemultinationalsthatreportsizable

earningsinforeignlow-taxjurisdictionswhileprofits recordedintheUnitedStatesaregenerallytaxedatarate above15%.China,France,Germany,andJapanwheremultinationals’ affiliatesusuallyencountereffectivetaxrates higherthan15%wouldseetheirtaxdeficitshrinkaswell.

Table2Revenuesofa15%GlobalMinimumTaxWithCarve-Outsof5%onTangibleAssetsandPayrollUndertheIncome InclusionRule(HeadquartersCollection)andtheQualifiedDomesticTop-UpTax(HostCountryCollection)in2021EURBillion

ParentCountry

HeadquartersCountryCollection (IncomeInclusionRule) in2021EURbn

HostCountryCollection (QualifiedDomesticMin.Top-UpTax) in2021EURbn

ParentCountry

HeadquartersCountryCollection (IncomeInclusionRule) in2021EURbn

HostCountryCollection (QualifiedDomesticMin.Top-UpTax) in2021EURbn

ParentCountry

HeadquartersCountryCollection (IncomeInclusionRule) in2021EURbn

HostCountryCollection (QualifiedDomesticMin.Top-UpTax) in2021EURbn

ThistablepresentsestimationsofrevenuegainsundertheheadquartersandtheQMDTTscenarios.Undertheheadquartersscenario,itisthecountry wheretheMNEisheadquarteredthatcollectstop-uptaxeswhereastheyarecollectedbythehostcountryundertheQDMTT.Estimationsarepresented withlong-runcarve-outs.

*Itisassumedinthesimulationinthisstudythattheglobalrevenuesumisthesameunderbothscenarios.Pleasenotethatnotalljurisdictionsinthe samplewereincludedasthetablewouldbeunreasonable.Therefore,thesumishigherthanthatofindicatedcountry-specificrevenuesinthetable.Smaller differencesareduetorounding.

+ CbCRreportingcountrycomprisesallofthecountriesaboveexceptforCyprus,Czechia,Estonia,Hungary,Latvia,Malta,Poland,Portugal,and Slovakia.

Initially,revenueswouldbedistributedamongagreater numberofcountriesundertheQDMTTcomparedtothe IIRunderwhichrevenuesseemtobeconcentratedamonga fewcountries.Thatisbecausemostofthelargemultinationalsareheadquarteredinafewcountries,especiallyin developedeconomies,withtheUnitedStatesextremelyin thelead.Table3breaksdownglobalrevenuegainsbased oncountries’ levelofdevelopmentusingtheUNclassification.G7countriesalonewouldcollectapproximatelyEUR 90billionintheheadquartersscenariowhileitwouldfall toEUR17billionunderhostcountrycollection. Developingcountries’ gainsseemverylimitedunderthe IIR;withQMDTTs,theywouldexperienceanincreasein theirpotentialtaxrevenues.TheEUR155billiontotal wouldbedistributedamong190jurisdictionsandseven regionswiththeQMDTTcomparedwitheighty-three countrieswiththeheadquartersmethodology,basedon thecurrentsampleinthisstudy.

Thesecomparisons,andparticularlytherevenuegains underthehostcountryscenario,mustbeinterpretedwith theunderstandingthattheymaynotbecompletelyaccuratesincetheyrepresentpotentialrevenuebeforeany behaviouraladjustmentsbymultinationalcompaniesor governments.Itislikelythatmultinationalsallocateless

Notes

profitstolow-taxjurisdictionswhentheincentivemargin decreasesduetotheminimumtax.

Thistablepresentsthedistributionoftaxrevenuesby countryclassification.TheheadquartersandQMDTTscenariosarepresentedwithcarve-outsinthelong-run.The totalnumberofcountrieswiththehostcountryscenario includes190countriesandsevenaggregatedregions: Asia,OtherAsia,andOtherAfricathatareclassifiedas developingandAmerica,OtherAmerica,Europe,and OtherEuropethataredesignatedasdeveloped.

EntirelyDomesticCompanies. TheEuropean Commission’sdirectiveproposalextendsthescopeofthe minimumtaxtoinclude ‘large-scalepurelydomestic groups ’,i.e.,companieswithaconsolidatedturnoverof atleastEUR750millionbutwithoutanyforeignaffiliates.BasedonORBISdata,182EUpurelydomestic companiesareidentifiedforwhichconsolidatedfinancials existandwhichoftheirconsolidatedturnovermeetsthe 750millionEURthreshold(see Appendix4).Morethan 75%ofthesecompaniesareoperatinginGermany(63), Italy(42),France(20),andtheNetherlands(18). However,overallrevenuesfromthesearemarginalwith aroundEUR35million.21 Beyondthelimitednumberof firmssubjecttotheproposedextensionoftheminimum

21 Thisamountisbasedonthefinancialsof170large-scalepurelydomesticgroupsforwhichsufficientconsolidateddatacouldbeobtained.Theauthorsalsohavethe individualfinancialsoftheparentcompaniesofseventy-nineotherpurelydomesticgroups.Includingtheminthesampleyieldsoverallrevenuesof approximatelyEUR54

Table3Revenuesofa15%GlobalMinimumTaxWithCarve-Outsof5%onTangibleAssetsandPayrollbyCountryClassification UndertheIncomeInclusionRuleandtheQualifiedDomesticTop-UpTaxin2021EURBillion

HeadquartersScenario(IncomeInclusionRule)

HostCountryScenario(QualifiedDomesticTop-Up Tax)

ClassificationNumberofCountriesRevenuein2021EURbnNumberofCountriesRevenuein2021EURbn Developed34133.44195.5 ofwhichG7789.5717.4 Developing482110849.2 Intransition10.2130.1 Leastdeveloped00350.1 Undetermined---10.5 Total 83154.5197154.5

tax,twofactorsmayexplaintheselowrevenuegains. First,large-scalepurelydomesticgroupsencounterrelativelyhighmedianandmeaneffectivetaxratesof27% and25%,respectively,overthesample.Second,substance-basedcarve-outshaveasignificantimpacton thesefirmswiththelong-run(firstyear)carve-outrates wherebythetaxbaseisreducedby22%(38%)on average.

6DISCUSSION

6.1 EstimatesinLightofRelatedStudies

Theestimatesinthisstudycontributetoagrowing literatureontherevenueeffectsofaglobalminimum taxand,moreprecisely,PillarTwo.Inthissubsection, theresultsarerelatedwithpriorestimatesanddiscuss differencesinmethodsandresults.

TheOECD’s(2020)EconomicImpactAssessmentwas thefirstthatmodelledrevenuesfromPillarTwounder theIIR.TheyfindglobalrevenuesofUSD40to48 billionfora15%minimumtaxratewithoutcarve-outs beforeanybehaviouraladjustments.Thisismuchlower thantheglobalestimatesinthisstudy.However,dueto theuncertaintyofthecoexistencewiththeGILTI,their estimatesexcluderevenuesfromUSMNEsentirelyeven thoughitisthemainbeneficiarycountryundertheIIR. AdditionalrevenuesofEUR58billionareestimatedfor

Notes

theUnitedStatesinthisarticle.Furtherdifferencesmight arisefromslightlyvariousmethodologies,e.g.,incomputingtheETRs.

TheOECD(2021)providesanupdatedestimateina pressreleaseaccompanyingtheglobaltaxagreementof PillarTwo:Theagreedminimumtaxwilllikelygenerate additionalrevenuesofapproximatelyUSD150billion(or aboutEUR127billion).Thisisbroadlyinaccordance withthisstudy’sfullsampleestimates.AdditionalrevenueofEUR139billionEUR(in2021)isestimatedwith firstyearcarve-outs.22 Unfortunately,therevisedOECD (2021)estimatesarenotbrokendownintocountry-bycountryrevenuesfromPillarTwo.

Devereuxetal.(2020)estimatethepotentialrevenues fromaglobalminimumtaxonacountry-by-countrybasis usingthedatabasecompiledbyTørslov,Wier,and Zucman(2020).Theyassumea10%minimumeffective taxratewithoutcarve-outprovisionsandfindthatthis wouldgenerateadditionalrevenuesofaboutUSD32 billion(almostEUR34billion,constant2021)globally orabout1.7%ofworldwidecorporateincometaxrevenues.Theestimatesinthisstudyaresignificantlyhigher duetoseveralreasons.First,aminimumtaxrateof15% isassumed.Ahighertaxrateleadstoalargerscopeof MNEsfallingunderrevenuecollectionandincreasestax revenuesmorethanproportionally.Fora15%minimum rate,Devereuxetal.(2020)findadditionalrevenuesof approximatelyUSD57to69billionin2012(aboutEUR

million(+53%).Theseamountsshouldbeconsideredasindicativeoftheorderofmagnitudeofthepotentialrevenuegainsfromtheextensionratherthanveryrobust estimates. See s.CoftheOnlineAppendixforresultsthataremoredetailedandcommentsonthemethodology.

22 TheECB’sUSD-EURmarketexchangeratefor2021of1.18274.AccordingtothepressreleasethataccompaniedthejointstatementofOct.2021, ‘theglobal minimumtaxagreement[ ]will see countriescollectaroundUSD150billioninnewrevenuesannually .However,themethodologiesusedtoobtainthisstudy s resultsandthisfigurecannotbecomparedasthecontentoftheproposalhaschangedsubstantiallysincethereleaseoftheOECD’sEconomicImpactAssessmentin Oct.2020.

61to74billion,constant2021).23 Second,followingthe directiveproposaloftheEuropeanCommission,therevenuesdrawnbyEUMemberStatesfromtheunder-taxed profitsofdomesticsubsidiariesareincluded.This accountsforEUR28.4billion(constant2021)inthis study’sbenchmarkcomputationswithoutcarve-outs.24 Eventually,despitedifferencesintheestimatedamounts ofrevenuegains,comparableconclusionsaredrawn regardingthedistributionalconsequencesofPillarTwo. Inparticular,thelargesteconomiesareexpectedtodraw themostadditionaltaxrevenuesastheyhostnumerous largemultinationalcompanies.However,somesmaller low-taxjurisdictionsthathaveattractedmanyheadquartersalsobenefitsubstantiallyfromtheglobalminimum tax(especiallyHongKongandPanamainDevereuxetal. (2020)).

Thereareanumberofstudiesthatfocusonsome specificcountries.FortheUnitedStates,Clausingetal. (2021)estimatepossibletaxrevenuesfroma21%minimumtaxrateofUSD48billion(2021current)yearly basedoninternalrevenueservice(IRS)data.Itisdifferent fromthevaluefoundinthisarticleofaboutEUR89 billion(constant2021)yearly.Thedissimilaritiesmight bebecauseClausingetal.(2021)onlyattributetwo-thirds oftheirestimatedrevenuesofUSD61billiontothe UnitedStatesandaccountforreducedprofitshifting.

Laffitte etal. (2021) providemodel-basedrevenueestimatesforFrance,Germany,andtheUnitedStatesbased onabilateralbalanceofpaymentsandamodelthattakes intoaccountdirecttaxgainsfromthetop-uptax,indirect taxgainsduetoareductioninprofitshifting,andpossibletaxlossesduetorelocationofproductionsites.Fora globalminimumtaxof15%withoutcarve-outs,theyfind thatFrancecouldgenerateadditionalrevenuesofEUR6 billionannuallyintheshortrunwhichdecreasestoEUR 2billionafterbehaviouraladjustments.

ForGermany,theyfindrevenuesofEUR8billion annuallyintheshorttermandaboutEUR3billion aftermodelledbehaviouralresponses.Theorderofmagnitudeisapproximatelyinaccordancewiththeresultsin thisstudy.ForFrance,additionalrevenuesarefoundof EUR4billionannuallywithoutcarve-outsandEUR3.6 billionwithcarve-outs,bothslightlyloweramountsthat mightcomeaboutbecausetaxgainsfromrepatriated profitsarenotconsidered.ForGermany,ahigherrevenue

isestimated,ofEUR13billionannuallybeforecarve-outs andEUR10billionwithcarve-outs.Thisstudy’shigher estimatesmightarisefromtakingintoaccounttaxrevenuesfromundertaxedprofitsintheheadquarterscountry andnon-havensjurisdictionswhileLaffitteetal.(2021) focusonundertaxedprofitsinoffshorecentres.Revenues fromnon-havenjurisdictionsandrevenuesintheheadquarterscountryinthecaseofGermanyaresignificantin thisstudy’sestimations.Ingeneral,differencesinestimatesareexpectedhereduetothevariousdatasources anddifferentunderlyingmodels.25

Overall,thisstudy’sestimatesshowasimilarorderof magnitudetopriorstudies.Significantdifferencesinrevenueestimatesariseprimarilyduetothemodellingof differentestimatesoftheagreement.Specifically,revenue fromtheminimumtaxinEUheadquartersjurisdictions(as laidoutintheEUdirectivedraft),revenuesfromnon-tax havenswithlowETRs,andtaxhavensareincluded.Many relatedstudiesonlyestimaterevenuesfromoffshorecentres andtaxhavens.Thisworkismostprobablythefirstto providecountry-specificrevenueeffectsoftheglobalminimumtaxbasedontheOECD’sModelRulesandtheEU DirectivedraftofDecember2021includingtheIIRaswell astheQDMTTandthenegotiatedcarve-outprovisions.

6.2 ResultsinLightofFirms’ Behavioural Responses

Thefirst-roundestimatesoftherevenuegainsfroma globalminimumtaxbeforeanybehaviouraladjustments bymultinationalcompaniesorgovernmentsarepresented. However,theglobalminimumtaxislikelytoprofoundly affectagents’ incentiveswithconsequencesforthedistributionofprofitsorevenforcorporateincometaxsystems. First,theglobalminimumtaxwilllikelyreducethe intensityofmultinationalcompanies’ profitshifting. Manystudieshaveidentifiedhowlowertaxratesmake somejurisdictionsparticularlyattractiveformultinational companiesanddriveupwardstheamountofpre-taxprofitsrecordedthere.Severalstudieshavefoundasemielasticityofprofitswithrespecttotaxratedifferentials ofapproximately-0.8to-1(HeckemeyerandOveresch, 2017;Johansson,Skeie,SorbeandMenon,2017;Beeret al.2020;Dharmapala2014).Stateddifferently,aonepercentage-pointreductioninthetaxrateofajurisdiction

Notes

23 Forthisconversion,theECB smarketexchangerateisusedtoconvertUSDintoEURfor2012(1.2847887)andtheWorldEconomicOutlooknominalGDPgrowthratein EURbetween2012and2021(asmultiplier1.374317).

24 FurtherdiscrepanciesmightarisefromthefactthatDevereuxetal.’ s, supra n.7sampleincludesloss-makingandprofit-makingentitieswhiledatabaseinthisstudyis restrictedtothepositiveprofitssample.Additionally,Devereuxetal. s, supra n.7centralresultsarebasedon2012datawhilethecomputationsinthisstudyareon2017 dataandtheresultsaretransposedto2021accountingforinflationandfortheincreasesinmultinationalcompanies’ profits.

25 Twofurtherstudies,albeitwithaslightlydifferentsimulationtothisstudy,arethefirsttoestimaterevenuelossesofprofitshiftingusingmicroCbCrdata.Fuestetal. (2020)estimateaprofitshiftingmodelbasedontheGermanmicroCbCRdata.Theyfindthatpaperprofit-shiftingbyGermanMNEsaboveandbelowtheEUR 750 millionthresholdtotaxhavensinducedataxrevenuelossofEUR5.7billionyearly.BarbaraBratta,VeraSantomartino&PaoloAcciari, AssessingProfitShiftingUsing Country-by-CountryReports:ANon-linearResponsetoTaxRateDifferentials,DFWorkingpapers,11/2021(2021)useItalianCbCRdataandfindrevenuelosses(byusingthe differenceofthetaxpaidonprofitsshiftedtothecounterfactualoftaxationintheheadquarterscountry)ofEUR26billionforFrance,EUR6billion forGermany,andEUR 1billionforItaly.However,notethatthisaverydifferentsimulationtorevenuegainsundertheglobalminimumtax.

withrespecttootherjurisdictionsisassociatedwitha 0.8%to1%increaseinpretaxprofitsreportedbymultinationalsinthisjurisdiction.Moregenerally,thereisa strongerincentivetorecordprofitsinthedestinationof theshiftedincomewhenthereisasignificantdifferencein corporateincometaxratesbetweenthatcountryandthe countrywherethecompanyislocated.Moreover,Brattaet al.(2021)findthattheresponsetochangesintaxrate differentialsisnonlinearwithmuchhigherresponsesin taxhavens.Moreprecisely,theyfindthatprofitsbooked inalow-taxcountrywoulddecreasebyalmost6%(comparedto0.8%-1%above)ifthisjurisdictionincreasesits taxrateby1percentagepoint.A15%globalminimum taxthereforesubstantiallyreducesthecompany’sprofit shiftingincentive,inparticulartotaxhavens,bycurtailingthetaxratedifferential.Thisissueisdiscussedfurther andrevenueestimatesafterbehaviouraladjustmentsof firmswillbeprovidedinOnlineAppendix2. Pastestimatesoftheresponsesofpretaxprofitstotax ratedifferentials,however,maybelimitedtoanticipatethe reactionofmultinationalcompaniestoastructuralchange intheinternationaltaxsystemlikePillarTwo.Viaits GILTIprovision,theUSTaxCutandJobsActof2017 introducedaminimumtaxontheglobalprofitsofsome multinationalsforthefirsttime.Despiteverysignificant differenceswiththeGloBEproposal(e.g.,withrespectto theminimumeffectivetaxrate,theabsenceof ‘jurisdictionalblending’,orsubstance-basedincomeexclusions),the GILTIisprobablytheonlyprecedentavailabletostudy companies’ responsestoaglobalminimumtax.Analysing itseffects,Garcia-Bernardo,Janský,andZucman(2021) findthattheshareofforeignpretaxprofitsrecordedbyUS multinationalcompaniesintaxhavensremainedstable from2015to2020atapproximately50–60%.Overall, theeffectivetaxratefacedbyUSmultinationalsontheir foreignincomedidnotincreaseaftertheintroductionof theGILTI.Whiledifferencesbetweenthetworulesmake itimpossibletodrawanyassertiveconclusion,thisresult doesquestionthereductionintheintensityofmultinationals’ profitshiftingthatmaybeexpectedfromthe GloBEproposal.However,Clausing(2020)contendsthat, iftheGILTIwasonacountry-by-countrylevelasthe proposaloftheminimumtax,itwouldreduceprofitshiftingmoresubstantiallythanattheMNElevelwhereblendingbetweenincomefromlowandhighcountriescould eliminateGILTIpayments.

Ifmultinationalcompaniesrespondbyrepatriatinga partoftheirprofitsfromtaxhavenstohigher-tax

jurisdictions,thiswouldreducetheamountofundertaxed corporateincomeandthusaggregaterevenuegainsfrom theglobalminimumtax.Theeffectonthegeographical distributionofrevenues,however,isambiguousbecauseit dependsonwheremultinationalsredirecttheirprofitsand ontheheterogeneousintensityofprofitshiftingactivities acrossheadquarterscountries.26 UndertheIIR,thereductionofpotentialrevenuesmightalsooccurifMNEsmove theirheadquarterstoanothercountry.Thisdependson whethersomecountrieswouldofferincentivessuchastax credits.However,anumberofcountrieshaveanexisting penaltyfeeforMNEsthatwishtochangetheir headquarters.

Second,substance-basedcarve-outsalsoaffectthe incentivesofmultinationalcompaniesandtax jurisdictions.27 Indeed,carve-outsshieldpartofthe undertaxedprofitsfromtheglobal15%minimumtax inproportiontopayrollexpensesandtangibleassets. Profitscanbetaxedataneffectiveratesignificantly smallerthan15%evenafterPillarTwoapplieswithan adequateamountofgenuineeconomicactivityinajurisdictionandasufficientlyloweffectivetaxrate.To minimizetheirglobaltaxpayments,companiescould thereforeconcentrateboththeirpre-taxprofitsandtheir realeconomicactivity(i.e.,employeesandtangibleassets) inlow-taxjurisdictions.Governmentsmayalsohavea strongerincentivetoprovidepreferentialtaxtreatments tomultinationalcompaniesthatgeneraterealeconomic activityintheirterritoryviathedevelopmentofspecial low-taxeconomiczones,forinstance.Whilecarve-outsdo notimpacttheeffectivenessoftheglobalminimumtaxto curbpurepaperprofitshifting,theeffectontaxplanning practicesandinternationaltaxcompetitionismore ambiguous.Importantly,forthisstudy’sanalysis,behaviouralresponsesinvolvingthesubstance-basedincome exclusionmayaffectboththeaggregaterevenuegains fromtheglobalminimumtaxandtheirdistribution.

6.3 ResultsinLightofPossibleGovernments’ Responses

Third,theglobalminimumtaxcouldinducegovernments ’ responsesintermsofinvestmentattractingpolicies thatmightcounteractthereducedprofit-shiftingintensity.Intheirtheoreticalwork,Janeba&Schjelderup (2022)suggestthattheminimumtaxwouldreduceprofit shifting,however,thetaxmightincreasetheimportance ofattractingactualforeigninvestments.Thiswouldresult Notes

26 TheOECD’sEconomicImpactAssessment(OECD, TaxChallengesArisingfromDigitalisation – EconomicImpactAssessment:InclusiveFrameworkonBEPS,OECD/G20Base ErosionandProfitShiftingProject(Paris:OECDPublishing2020))ofOct.2020developedamethodologytotakeintoaccountareductionintheintensityofprofitshifting activitiesintheirrevenueestimatesforPillarTwo.

27 MichaelP.Devereux,JohnVella,MartinSimmler&HeydonWardell-Burrus, WhatIstheSubstance-BasedCarve-OutUnderPillar2?AndHowWillItAffectTaxCompetition?, Econ.Pol.Pol yBrief39(Nov.2021),ontheonehand,andJohannesBecker&JoachimEnglisch, GloBEMinimumTaxation:CalculatingtheLocalETRWithCarve-Outs, KluwerInternationalTaxBlog(2021),linkontheotherhaveengagedinamorethoroughdiscussionoftheexpectedeffectsofsubstance-basedcarve-outsoninternational corporateincometaxcompetition.Thisstudymainlyfocusesontheeffectsonrevenuegainsandtheirdistribution.

inintensifiedtaxcompetitionthroughpossibletaxcredits.Johannesen(2022)arguesthatthenetwelfareeffectof theminimumtaxwillonlybeunambiguouslypositiveif thepolicysucceedsineffectivelyendingprofitshifting.If itfailsthisgoal,itmightleadtoareallocationoffunds fromnon-havenfirmstotaxhavengovernmentsviathe increaseinequilibriumtaxratesintaxhavens.28

Further,themodelrulesreleasedbytheOECDin December2021introducedthepossibilityforhostcountriestocollectthetop-uptaxesviaQDMTTs.Thisgives thehostcountrythepriorityofcollectionovertheheadquarterscountry.Dependingonthedesignconstraints imposedonQDMTTs,thetotalrevenuescollectedby thatmeansmaydifferfromIIRrevenuegainsdueto partiallyownedentities(Noked,2022).Additionally,as emphasizedinthecomparisonofthetwoscenariosinthis study(section4),itwouldchangetheirdistribution.Two polarcasesarepresented – first,afullimplementationof theIIRwithoutanycollectionundertheQDMTTand, second,thecaseinwhichalljurisdictionsadopta QDMTT.Intheory,hostcountrieshaveastraightforward incentivetoimplementadomesticminimumtax,i.e., theywouldsimplycollecttop-uptaxesthatmultinational companiesarerequiredtopayundertheglobalminimum tax.29 Devereuxetal.(2022)goevenfurtherandcontend thatjurisdictionsareincentivizedtotaxmultinational companiessolelythroughtheQDMTTinacompetitive internationaltaxenvironment.Inpractice,however,a hybridcasebetweenbothpolarcasesismorelikelytobe implementeddependingontheadministrativecostof introducingtheseinstrumentsandthediscretionarydecisionsofgovernments.30 Aportionofmultinationals’ undertaxedprofitswouldbetaxedfirstbyhostcountries throughtheQDMTT.Thereafter,theIIRwouldbecome relevantwheneverQDMTTsdonotclosethegaptoa 15%effectiverate.Thiswouldgiveheadquarterscountriesthepossibilitytocollectpartoftheminimumtax revenue.Last,theUTPRwouldeventuallyapplyifthere isremainingincomethathasnotbeencollectedbythe hostortheheadquarterscountry.31

Fourth,somecountriesmightwanttoadoptthe QDMTTinordertocollecttherevenuesbutoffertax creditsatthesametimetopreservetheircompetitiveness. NotallcountrieswillimplementtheQDMTTbecauseit wouldeitherbeexpensiveforthemorbecausetheyarenot awareofit.However,thosewhodoimplementthe QDMTTbyraisingtheETRmightbeincentivizedto

introducesometaxcreditsinordertomaintainalevelof taxcompetition.Itshouldbenotedthatthe15%minimumtaxisstillalowertaxratethanthoseinmany countriesastheaveragecorporatestatutoryrateis approximately21%intheEU(KPMG2021).Thus, thereisapossibilitythattherearenomultinationals fromcountrieswitharatecloseto15%.Countrieswith verylowtaxrateswouldbemostlyaffectedunlessthey introducesomeotherincentives.Theeffectivenessof PillarTwomightbeweakenedbytheintroductionof suchformsoftaxcreditsbylowtaxjurisdictions.Since PillarTwoharmonizesthecorporatetaxrateamongthe differentcountries,somejurisdictionsmightintroducetax creditstooffsetthetopuptaxesthatanMNEmustpay. Thecountrythatintroducesthemtherebypreservesits fiscalcompetitionfeaturewithoutvisiblyhavingalowtax rate.Thismightleadtoataxcreditcompetitionamong countrieswhowouldliketocompeteoverattracting MNE’s.Incentivessuchastaxholidays,freetradezones, andlandandinfrastructurepaidforbygovernmentsto attractfirmswillbeattractivetosomecountriesinthe wakeoftheglobalminimumtaxaccordingtoJanebaand Schjelderup(2022).

ItshouldbenotedthattheOECDmodelrulesfurther differentiatebetween ‘qualifiedrefundabletaxcredits’ thatshallbetreatedasincomeinthecomputationof GloBEincomeand ‘non-qualifiedrefundabletaxcredits’ thataretreatedasareductiontocoveredtaxesinthe refundperiod.Theresultofthisisthattheuseofthe non-qualifiedtaxincentivesortaxcredits – becausethey reducecoveredtaxes – mayultimatelyreducetheETRof anentitybelow15%(FerreiraLiottietal.,2022).Inthat case,theUTPRcouldbeused,allowingothercountriesto collectthebenefitsofthetaxcreditsandincentives grantedbysomegovernments.

6.4 FurtherConsiderations

Fifth,thedistributionofrevenuegainsfromtheglobal minimumtaxwilldependonthetreatmentofUSmultinationalcompanies’ GILTItop-uptaxpayments.Themodel rulesdonotspecifytheconditionsofthecoexistencebetween PillarTwoandtheGILTI.OnepossibilityisthattheGILTI willbetreatedasanIIR.Inthiscase,thehostcountry collectionviaaQDMTTwouldhavepriorityoverthe GILTI,andpotentialrevenueswouldcorrespondtothe hostcountrycollectiondescribedinTable2.However,if

28 N.Johannesen, TheGlobalMinimumTax.In:JournalofPublicEconomics (2022forthcoming)onlytakesintoaccounttheIIR.

29 ThisideaisdevelopedfurtherintheOnlineAppendix.

30 Afewcountriesarealreadyexplicitlyconsideringtheintroductionofaqualifieddomestictop-uptax.Thisisthecase,forinstance,intheUnitedKingdom(HMTreasury, OECDPillar2 – ConsultationonImplementation (2022),openconsultationdocument,link)orSwitzerland(Conseilfederal, Rapportexplicatifrelatifàl’arrêtfédéralsurune impositionparticulièredesgrandsgroupesd’entreprises(Miseen œuvreduprojetconjointdel’OCDEetduG20surl’impositiondel’économienumérique) (2022),onlineaccesslink(reference availableinFrench,GermanandItalian)).SpecializedpressarticlesalsomentionHongKongorSingapore.Additionally,theUnitedArabEmirateshasannouncedthe introductionofanewcorporateincometaxsystemthatincludesa15%rateontheearningsofmultinationalcompaniesinthescopeofPillarTwo.

31 TheUTPRwasnotsimulatedinthisstudy.

taxespaidundertheGILTIareincludedinthe ‘adjusted coveredtaxes’ oftheGloBEproposal,thiswouldraisethe effectivetaxratescomputedforUSmultinationalcompanies andtherebyreduce – possiblydowntozeroiftheminimum effectivetaxrateretainedfortheGILTIissufficiently high – thetop-uptaxestobecollectedbyhostcountries undertheQDMTT.Revenuesfromtheundertaxedprofitsof USmultinationalcompanieswouldthenbecollectedbythe UnitedStatesregardlessofwhetherthehostjurisdictionhas introducedaQDMTT.Inthiscase,theestimatesforthefull implementationoftheQDMTT (Table2,rightcolumn)in whichallhostcountriescollecttheglobalminimumtax wouldseverelyunderestimatetherevenuegainsforthe UnitedStates.Therewouldalsobeanoverestimationof therevenuegainsforthejurisdictionswhereUSmultinationalcompaniesbookundertaxedprofits.Hence,theonly wayforthesourcecountrytoretaintheserevenueswouldbe toraiseitscorporateincometaxrate.

Last,itisworthmentioningthattherevenuesfromthe globalminimumtaxmightdecreaseifPillarOneis introducedalongwithPillarTwo.Thiswouldoccurdue tothefactthatsomerevenueswouldhavebeenredistributedaccordingtoPillarOneandthustaxedwhichwould raisetheETR.Thiswouldbelimitedtotheapproximately100largestandmostprofitableMNEsthatare inscopeofPillarOne,accordingtotheOECD.

7CONCLUSION

InOctober2021,137countriesandjurisdictionsagreedon theimplementationofamajorreformoftheinternational corporatetaxsystem,i.e.,aglobalminimumtaxof15%on largemultinationalcompanies’ income.Thisarticlepresentssimulationsoftherevenueeffectsoftheglobalminimumtax.Whiletheminimumtaxrateof15%andcarveoutratesareset,whocollectsthetaxseemstobemore ambiguous.Ontheonehand,theIIRgivesheadquarters countriestherighttotaxtheundertaxedaffiliatesoftheir multinationals;ontheotherhand,theQDMTTgivesthe prioritytohostjurisdictionstocollecttop-uptaxesfrom thesubsidiariesthatarerecordingprofitsintheirterritory. Thisarticlesimulatethefirst-roundrevenueeffectsofthe fullimplementationofbothrulesinastaticframework. Thegeographicaldistributionofrevenuegainsamong countriesheavilydependsonwhichjurisdictionisgranted thepriorityoraccesstoapplytheminimumtax.

Aglobalminimumtaxof15%,forwhichtheheadquarterscountrycollectstheadditionalrevenues,wouldgenerate aboutEUR67billionfortheEUandaroundEUR179 billionfortheeighty-threeparentcountriesinthisstudy’ s sample.Thisamountdecreasessubstantiallywiththecarveoutsestablishedinthemodelrules.Withthelong-run carve-outratesof5%forbothtangibleassetsandpayroll, EUrevenuegainswoulddecreasebyabout18%frominitiallyEUR67billiontoEUR55billion.Nontheless,thetotal revenuesofaglobalminimum taxwouldstillamounttoan increaseincurrentcorporateincometaxrevenuesofalmost

16%fortheEU.ThelargestbeneficiariesoftheIIRwould betheUnitedStatesthatwouldcollectextrarevenueof morethanEUR50billionandlargeEuropeancountries suchasGermanycollectingaboutEUR13billionorthe UnitedKingdomwithaboutEUR7billon.Addingtothat, somelow-taxjurisdictionsthathaveattractedanumberof headquartersoverthelastdecadeswouldgainsubstantial revenuesfromtheminimumtaxlike,forexample,Ireland withmorethanEUR12billionandLuxembourgwithEUR 6billion.UnderthefullimplementationoftheIIR,revenueswouldbeunequallydistributedacrosstheglobe. Developedandhigh-incomecountrieswouldgainmore extrarevenuesfromtheglobalminimumtaxthandevelopingandlow-incomecountries.

IfallcountriesimplementaQDMTT,revenueswould onlybecollectedincountrieswhereundertaxedaffiliates operate.Inthatcase,thepotentialrevenuesofmanylarge westerncountrieslikeFrance,Germany,andtheUnited Stateswouldsubstantiallydecrease.However,revenues wouldaccrueforapproximately197jurisdictionsinthe world.Inbothscenarios,theleastdevelopedcountries gainnoorverylimitedrevenues.

Alloftheestimatesinthisstudyarefirst-roundeffects beforethebehaviouralresponsesofmultinationalsorgovernments.Thesewouldparticularlyaffectthegeographical distributionofrevenues.Themagnitudeofbehavioural responsesisunknown.Whilestudiessuggestthatan increaseintaxationinlow-taxcountriescouldtriggera strongdecreaseinprofitsthatarerecordedinthosejurisdictions,theexampleoftheGILTI – theclosestattempt untilnowatasystematicminimumtaxationformultinationals – hasshownverylimitedeffectsontheeffective taxrateandprofitshiftingpatternsofmultinationals.

8REFERENCES

RitaAlmeida, TheLaborMarketEffectsofForeignOwned Firms,72(1)J.Int’lEcon.75–96(2007).

MonaBaraké,TheresaNeef,Paul-EmmanuelChouc& GabrielZucman, CollectingtheTaxDeficitofMultinational Companies:SimulationsfortheEuropeanUnion,EUTax ObservatoryReportNo.1(2021),onlineaccesslink.

MonaBaraké,TheresaNeef,Paul-EmmanuelChouc& GabrielZucman, MinimizingtheMinimumTax?The CriticalEffectofSubstanceCarve-Outs,EUTax ObservatoryNoteNo.1(2021),onlineaccesslink.

MonaBaraké,TheresaNeef,Paul-EmmanuelChouc& GabrielZucman, RevenueEffectsoftheGlobalMinimum Tax:Country-by-CountryEstimates,EUTaxObservatory NoteNo.2(2021),onlineaccesslink.

JohannesBecker&JoachimEnglisch, GloBEMinimum Taxation:CalculatingtheLocalETRWithCarve-Outs, KluwerInternationalTaxBlog,link.

SebastianBeer,RuudDeMooij&LiLiu, International CorporateTaxAvoidance:AReviewoftheChannels, Magnitudes,andBlindSpots,34(5)J.Econ.Surveys660–688(2020).

JenniferBlouin&LeslieRobinson, DoubleCounting Accounting:HowMuchProfitofMultinationalEnterprisesIs ReallyinTaxHavens?,SSRN(2020).

BarbaraBratta,VeraSantomartino&PaoloAcciari, AssessingProfitShiftingUsingCountry-by-CountryReports: ANon-linearResponsetoTaxRateDifferentials,DF Workingpapers,11/2021(2021).

KimberlyClausing,EmmanuelSaez&GabrielZucman, EndingCorporateTaxAvoidanceandTaxCompetition:APlan toCollecttheTaxDeficitofMultinationals,UCLASchoolof Law,Law-EconResearchPaper,20-12(2021).

KimberlyClausing, ProfitShiftingBeforeandAftertheTax CutsandJobsAct,73(4)Nat’lTaxJ.1233–1266(2020).

Conseilfederal, Rapportexplicatifrelatifàl’arrêtfédéral suruneimpositionparticulièredesgrandsgroupesd’entreprises (Miseen œuvreduprojetconjointdel’OCDEetduG20sur l’impositiondel’économienumérique) (2022),onlineaccess link(referenceavailableinFrench,GermanandItalian).

MichaelP.Devereux,FrançoisBares,SarahClifford, JudithFreedman,IremGüçeri,MartinMcCarthy, MartinSimmler&JohnVella, TheOECDGlobalAntibaseErosionProposal (OxfordUniversityCentrefor BusinessTaxation2020).

MichaelP.Devereux,JohnVella,MartinSimmler& HeydonWardell-Burrus, WhatIstheSubstance-Based Carve-OutUnderPillar2?AndHowWillItAffectTax Competition?,Econ.Pol.Pol’yBrief39(Nov.2021).

MichalP.Devereux,JohnVella&HeydonWardellBurrus, Pillar2:RuleOrder,Incentives,andTaxCompetition, OxfordUniversityCentreforBusinessTaxationPolicyBrief (2021).

DhammikaDharmapala, WhatDoWeKnowAboutBase ErosionandProfitShifting?AReviewoftheEmpirical Literature,35(4)FiscalStud.421–448(2014).

EuropeanCentralBank(ECB), EuroForeignExchange ReferenceRates,ECB/Eurosystempolicyandexchange rates(2021),onlineaccesslink.

B.FerreiraLiotti,J.W.Ndubai,R.Wamuyu,I. Lazarov&J.Owens, TheTreatmentofTaxIncentives UnderPillarTwo,availableatSSRN(2022).

JavierGarcia-Bernardo&PetrJanský, ProfitShiftingof MultinationalCorporationsWorldwide,arXiv,General Economics(2022).

JavierGarcia-Bernardo,PetrJanský&GabrielZucman, DidtheTaxCutsandJobsActReduceProfitShiftingbyUS MultinationalCompanies? (2021),preliminarydraft.

JostH.Heckemeyer&MichaelOveresch, Multinationals’ ProfitResponsetoTaxDifferentials:EffectSizeandShifting Channels,50(4)Can.J.Econ.965–994(2017).

FredrikHeyman,FredrikSjöholm&PatrikTingvall, IsThere ReallyaForeignOwnershipWagePremium?EvidencefromMatched Employer-EmployeeData,73(2)J.Int’lEcon.355–376(2007). HMTreasury, OECDPillar2 – Consultationon Implementation (2022),openconsultationdocument,link. ThomasHorst&AlexCuratolo, AssessingtheDouble CountofPretaxProfitintheIRSSummaryofCbCDatafor Fiscal2017,98(4)TaxNotesInt’l(2020).

InternationalLaborOrganization(ILO), MeanNominal MonthlyEarningsofEmployeesbySexandEconomicActivity (LocalCurrency) – Monthly,ILOStatistics(2021),online accesslink.

InternationalMonetaryFund(IMF), April2021 Database,WorldEconomicOutlook(WEO)database (2021),onlineaccesslink.

E.Janeba&G.Schjelderup, TheGlobalMinimumTax RaisesMoreRevenuesThanYouThink,orMuchLess, DiscussionPaper(2022).

N.Johannesen, TheGlobalMinimumTax.In:Journalof PublicEconomics (2022forthcoming).

ÅsaJohansson,ØysteinBieltvedtSkeie,StéphaneSorbe &CarloMenon, TaxPlanningbyMultinationalFirms: Firm-LevelEvidencefromaCross-CountryDatabase,OECD EconomicsDepartmentWorkingPapers,No.1355(Paris: OECDPublishing2017).

SebnemKalemli-Ozcan,BentSorensen,CarolinaVillegasSanchez,VadymVolosovych&SevcanYesiltas, Howto ConstructNationallyRepresentativeFirmLevelDatafromthe OrbisGlobalDatabase:NewFactsandAggregateImplications, NBERworkingpaperseries,no.w21558.Cambridge, Mass:NationalBureauofEconomicResearch,2015(2022).

KPMG, CorporateTaxRatesTable (2021),onlineaccess link.

SébastienLaffitte,JulienMartin,MathieuParenti, BaptisteSouillard&FaridToubal, Taxationof Multinationals:DesignandQuantification,Focus,No. 064bis-2021.Conseild’analyseéconomique(2021).

NoamNoked, TheCaseforDomesticMinimumTaxeson Multinationals,SSRN(2022).

OECD, TaxChallengesArisingfrom Digitalisation – EconomicImpactAssessment:Inclusive FrameworkonBEPS,OECD/G20BaseErosionandProfit ShiftingProject(Paris:OECDPublishing2020).

OECD, ImportantDisclaimerRegardingtheLimitationsof theCountry-by-CountryReportStatists (2021),https://www. oecd.org/tax/tax-policy/anonymised-and-aggregated-cbcrstatistics-disclaimer.pdf.

EmmanuelSaez&GabrielZucman, TheTriumphof Injustice – HowtheRichDodgeTaxesandHowtoMake ThemPay (NewYork,NY:WWNorton2020).

ThomasR.Tørsløv,LudvigS.Wier&Gabriel Zucman, TheMissingProfitsofNations,NBERWorking PaperSeries,No.24701(2018).

OECD, TableI – AggregateTotalsbyJurisdiction, CorporateTaxStatistics(2020–2021),onlineaccesslink anddatalimitationsdisclaimer.

ThomasR.Tørsløv,Ludvig S.Wier&GabrielZucman, The MissingProfitsofNations (2019),Estimatesupdatedto2016and 2017,tablesavailableonmissingprofits.world.

UnitedNations, WorldEconomicSituationandProspects 2020 (2020),onlineaccesslink.

KhadijaVanderStraaten,NiccolòPisani&AnsKolk, UnravelingtheMNEWagePremium,Journalof InternationalBusinessStudies(2020),SSRN,https:// ssrn.com/abstract=3717151.

9APPENDIX

1. HEADQUARTERSSCENARIO

REVENUEGAINSBYTYPEOFPARTNER

JURISDICTION

TableA115%WithCarve-OutsSplitinDomestic,Non-taxHavens,TaxHavens(5.3)in2021BillionEUR

ParentCountryTotalRevenueGains in2021EURbn FromTaxHavensFromForeign Non-havens FromDomesticProfits

Austria 2.20.00.51.8

Belgium 3.31.11.30.9

Cyprus 0.20.10.10.0

CzechRepublic 0.10.00.00.0

Denmark 1.50.40.21.0

Estonia 0.10.00.00.1

Finland 1.30.00.40.9

France 3.53.50.10.0

Germany 9.93.41.65.0

Greece 1.70.01.60.0

Hungary 0.40.00.00.4

Ireland 11.50.09.02.5

Italy 2.60.61.30.8

Latvia 0.10.00.00.1

Luxembourg 5.01.12.31.7

Malta 0.10.00.00.1

Netherlands 2.00.00.02.0

Poland 2.70.00.02.6

Portugal 0.00.00.00.0

Romania 0.10.00.00.1

Slovakia 0.00.00.00.0

Slovenia 0.00.00.00.0

Spain 3.60.42.11.0

Sweden 2.30.02.20.1

EUtotal54.210.622.820.9

Thistablepresentsestimationsfortheadditionalrevenues collectedbyEUMemberStatesundertheheadquartersscenario.Revenuegainsaredecomposeddependingonthenature ofthejurisdictionwheretheundertaxedprofitsarebooked.

Thesecanbereporteddomestically,inaforeigntaxhaven, orinaforeignnon-havenjurisdiction.Thelatterinclude theregionalaggregatesreportedbysomeparentcountriesin thetabulatedcountry-by-countryreportstatistics.

10APPENDIX 2. EFFECTOFTHEMINIMUM RATE

TableA2OverviewoftheHeadquartersScenarioforDifferentMinimumEffectiveTaxRatesin2021EURBillion

ParentCountry

RevenueGains(EURbn)DependingontheMinimumEffectiveTaxRateRetained 15%21%25%30%

France3.613.521.231.4

Germany10.124.635.549,6

EUtotal55.2117.9165.7228.0

Changein%114%40%38%

UnitedStates54.488.7114.3149.4

CbCR-reporting141.2273.3373.5504.9 Changein%94%37%35%

Fullsample154.5295.2416.4574.9

Changein%91%41%38%

Thistablepresentsrevenuegainestimatesfortheheadquartersscenario,whilevaryingtheminimumeffective taxratefrom15%to30%.Carve-outsof5%oftangible assetsand5%ofpayrollareapplied.Themore-thanproportionalincreaseinadditionalrevenueswiththe minimumrateisduetothecombinationoftwomechanisms,i.e.,whentheminimumrateincreases,top-uptaxes leviedonprofitsalreadyinthescopeoftheruleincrease andmoreprofitsaredeemedundertaxed,therebyfalling intothescopeoftherule.

11APPENDIX 3: HOSTCOUNTRY COLLECTION (QDMTT) FOROTHER JURISDICTIONS

TableA3RevenuesQDMTTScenarioforOtherJurisdictions WithMoreThanEUR1Million

Country

HostCountryCollection (QDMTT)in2021 EURbn

Mauritius1.083

UnitedArabEmirates0.606

ChineseTaipei0.202

Uruguay0.102

Country

HostCountryCollection (QDMTT)in2021 EURbn

Morocco0.061

Egypt0.058

CostaRica0.050

Russia0.049

Serbia0.048

Thailand0.047

Venezuela0.044

Qatar0.040

DominicanRepublic0.034

Ecuador0.034

EquatorialGuinea0.030

Myanmar0.028

NewZealand0.028

VietNam0.027

Israel0.025

Country

HostCountryCollection (QDMTT)in2021 EURbn

Ukraine0.024

Ghana0.023

Paraguay0.022

PapuaNewGuinea0.019

Algeria0.018

Iran0.017

Philippines0.016

Kuwait0.015

SriLanka0.015

Zambia0.014

BurkinaFaso0.014

Kazakhstan0.013

Botswana0.013

Oman0.013

Laos0.013

SaudiArabia0.013

Turkey0.012

Congo0.010

Micronesia0.009

Côted’Ivoire0.009

Uganda0.008

SouthSudan0.008

Mozambique0.008

Monaco0.007

Liechtenstein0.007

UnitedStatesVirgin Islands 0.006

Liberia0.006

Bolivia0.005

Georgia0.005

Country

HostCountryCollection (QDMTT)in2021 EURbn

Nigeria0.004

Lebanon0.004

Iraq0.003

Cambodia0.003

Senegal0.003

Greenland0.003

BosniaandHerzegovina0.002

Gabon0.002

Eswatini0.002

Bangladesh0.002

AmericanSamoa0.002

Mali0.002

Mongolia0.002

Tunisia0.002

Colombia0.002

CaboVerde0.001

BruneiDarussalam0.001

Yemen0.001

Palau0.001

Guam0.001

Europe13.782

Americas5.094

Africa1.863

Asia1.792

Undetermined10.540

Thistablepresentstherevenuegainestimatesforthe hostcountry(QDMTT)scenarioforotherjurisdictions notdetailedinTable2.Onlyjurisdictionswithrevenues aboveEUR1millionareshown.Resultsarepresented withlongtermcarve-outs.

12APPENDIX 4: LOCATIONANDREVENUE POTENTIALOFLARGE-SCALEPURELY DOMESTICCOMPANIESINTHEEU

TableA4.1DistributionofEULarge-ScalePurelyDomestic GroupsAcrossHeadquartersCountries

Thistableshowshowthisstudy’ssampleoflarge-scale purelydomesticgroupsisdistributedacrossEUMemberStates.Intotal,182suchcompanieswereidentifiedfrom theORBISdatabasebasedonconsolidatedfinancials.The sampleusedinthisstudyallowtoestimateataxdeficit for170countries.

TableA4.2PotentialRevenueGainsfromEULarge-Scale PurelyDomesticGroups(in2021)

ParentCountryRevenueGains(EURm)

Thistablepresents,foreachEUMemberStatewith positivetaxdeficits,theestimatedrevenuegainsfrom theapplicationoftheminimu mtaxtolarge-scalepurely domesticgroups.Aminimumrateof15%andlong-run carve-outs(5%oftangibleassetsandpayroll)are assumed.

Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.