Farley, J. (2017). Market and Non-market Solutions to Ecological Crises. Solutions 8(1): 1-2. https://thesolutionsjournal.com/article/market-non-market-solutions-ecological-crises/
Editorial by Joshua Farley
Market and Non-market Solutions to Ecological Crises
Sascha Voss
Food prices at a grocery store in Barcelona, Spain.
E
cological crises ranging from climate change to biodiversity loss arise when self-interest outweighs the common good; for example, people aware of the catastrophic social costs of carbon emissions drive anyway because it is personally convenient. Markets, in theory, channel selfinterested, competitive behavior towards the common good, leading an increasing number of economists and environmentalists to argue that market mechanisms offer the most efficient solutions to environmental problems.1 People respond to higher prices—a tax on carbon—by using less. Industry responds to profit incentives—monopoly property rights to patented information—with environmentally-friendly innovations. These market mechanisms are certainly better than ignoring the costs of ecological degradation or investing nothing in green technology, but they
remain highly inefficient. Demand for essential resources, such as food and energy, is only responsive to price when expenditures account for a large share of the household budget. Internalizing the full ecological costs of agriculture would cause food prices to skyrocket. Yet, when food prices did soar from 2007 to 2008, rich countries scarcely noticed. Americans actually increased wheat consumption even as the price tripled.2 In contrast, in poor countries where food expenditures account for more than half the household budget, people slashed consumption,3 resulting in rising malnutrition, rioting, and political breakdown.4,5 Allocating the last loaf of bread to the overfed American who throws a third in the trash, rather than to the destitute African mother desperate to feed her starving children, is clearly inefficient.6 If society develops a clean, decentralized, dependable, and inexpensive
alternative to fossil fuels, it is equally inefficient to limit use to those who can pay monopoly prices, leaving others to burn coal. True, patents become part of the public domain after twenty years, but can we afford to delay the adoption of green technologies for that long? Most of the ecological problems we currently face are prisoners’ dilemmas: even when universal cooperation is clearly the best strategy for society as a whole, individuals are better off acting in their own self-interest regardless of what others do.7,8 Prisoners’ dilemmas can only be solved through institutions that successfully promote cooperation. Several articles in Solutions have called for one very promising cooperative institution: common asset trusts (CATs), designed to manage our shared natural and cultural heritage for the common good of this, and future generations.9-15 CATs can even use market mechanisms, such as auctioning off rights to resource extraction or waste emissions, and can use the resulting revenues to address the undue burdens on the poor and invest in the common good. Most global CATs will require detailed and complicated international agreements, which can be time consuming and difficult to negotiate. In contrast, a green technology CAT could be developed unilaterally and help pave the way for other CATs. A single wealthy nation, or even an individual, could start a CAT in green technologies by funding research— especially for sustainable agriculture and alternative energy—with results made freely available to all on the condition that any improvements are also open access.16 Unlike CATs for resource extraction or waste emissions, where the goal is to ration access to ensure sustainable consumption, the optimal property rule for information is open access—free, unlimited use for all. The major input into developing new technologies is information, so open
www.thesolutionsjournal.org | January-February 2017 | Solutions | 1
Editorial by Author 5. Ball, P. Acting on the global food crisis. The Lancet 386(10000): 1231 (2015). 6. Gustavsson, J, Cederberg, C, Sonesson, U, Otterdijk, RV & Meybeck, A. Global Food Losses and Food Waste: Exent, Causes and Prevention. (Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations, Rome, 2011). 7. Nowak, M & Highfield, R. SuperCooperators: Altruism, Evolution, and Why We Need Each Other to Succeed. (Free Press (Simon Schuster), New York, 2011). 8. Hardin, G. The Tragedy of the Commons. Science 162(3859): 1243–1248 (1968). 9. Barnes, P & McKibben, B. A Simple Market Mechanism to Clean Up Our Economy. The Solutions Journal 1(1): 30–38 (2009). 10. Costanza, R & Farley, J. What Should Be Done With the Revenues From a Carbon-Cap-and-Auction System? The Solutions Journal 1(1): 33 (2009). 11. Steffen, W, Rockström, J & Costanza R. How Defining Planetary Boundaries Can Transform Our Approach to Growth. The Solutions Journal 2(3): 59–65 (2011).
likeablerodent
12. Cooperstein, B. How Can We Fix Our Legal System to Protect the Environment? The Solutions Journal
LCD price tags at a market in Japan.
2(6): 96–98 (2011). 13. Cerrato, A. Levelling the Playing Field:
access lowers the costs of technological advance. Once a green technology exists, its value is maximized when adoption is maximized, at a price of zero. Furthermore, compared to profitdriven innovations, those funded by a CAT are more likely to help the poor or protect, restore, and create public goods.17-19 While all countries would ideally contribute funding to the best of their abilities, free-riding on the CAT would be impossible; more widespread adoption of green technologies benefits the funder, and will almost certainly lead to improvements in the technology. A fossil fuel economy is inherently competitive, since one person’s use of fossil fuels leaves less for others. In contrast, one country’s use of solar technologies does not leave less sunshine or technology for others. The energy transition required to avoid runaway climate change favors a more cooperative economy. Abundant research from across the sciences shows that humans are among the most cooperative species to have ever evolved, and identifies cultural
mechanisms that stimulate cooperation. One important mechanism is group membership, another is reciprocity stimulated by generosity.20-24 A green technology CAT achieves both of these. Anyone who chooses to use the technologies becomes a member, and initial generosity would undoubtedly stimulate reciprocal contributions. Technology alone will be unable to solve global ecological problems, but future negotiations for CATs that reduce waste emissions and resource extraction would be among members of the same group, and more open to reciprocal cooperation. References 1. Muradian, R et al. Markets for biodiversity and ecosystem services and the fatal attraction of win-win solutions. Conservation Letters 6(4): 274–279 (2013). 2. Wheat data. USDA [online] (2013). http://www.ers. usda.gov/data-products/wheat-data.aspx. 3. Farley, J, Schmitt Filho, A, Burke, M &Farr, M. Extending market allocation to ecosystem services: Moral and practical implications on a full and unequal planet. Ecological Economics 9(117): 244–252 (2015). 4. Berazneva, J & Lee, DR. Explaining the African food riots of 2007–2008: An empirical analysis. Food Policy 39: 28–39 (2013).
2 | Solutions | January-February 2017 | www.thesolutionsjournal.org
Strengthening Common Property in Honduran Legislation. The Solutions Journal 6(4): 69–75 (2015). 14. Costanza, R et al. The Perfect Spill: Solutions for Averting the Next Deepwater Horizon. The Solutions Journal 1(5): 17–20 (2010). 15. Costanza, R et al. The Future We Really Want. The Solutions Journal 4(4): 37–43 (2013). 16. Mustonen, M. Copyleft: the economics of Linux and other open source software. Information Economics and Policy 15(1): 99–121 (2003). 17. Mustonen, M. Copyleft: the economics of Linux and other open source software. Information Economics and Policy 15(1): 99–121 (2003). 18. Kubiszewski, I, Farley, J & Costanza R. The production and allocation of information as a good that is enhanced with increased use. Ecological Economics 69(6): 1344–1354 (2010). 19. Farley, J & Perkins S. Economics of Information in a Green Economy. In: Building a Green Economy (ed. Robertson, R). (Michigan State University Press, East Lansing, 2013). 20. Nowak, M & Highfield, R. SuperCooperators: Altruism, Evolution, and Why We Need Each Other to Succeed. (Free Press (Simon Schuster), New York, 2011). 21. Sober, E & Wilson, DS. Unto Others: The Evolution and Psychology of Unselfish Behavior. (Harvard University Press, Cambridge, 1998). 22. Wilson, DS. Evolution for Everyone: How Darwin’s Theory Can Change the Way We Think About Our Lives. (Delacorte Press, New York, 2007). 23. Wilson, EO. The Social Conquest of Earth. (Liveright Publishing Corporation, New York, 2012). 24. Henrich, J & Henrich, N. Why Humans Cooperate: A Cultural and Evolutionary Explanation. (Oxford University Press, New York, 2007).