Trinity Papers No. 37 - 'The 
Relevance 
of 
Keynesian
 Fiscal 
Policy 
Today
 
'

Page 1

The
Relevance
of
Keynesian
Fiscal
Policy
Today
 
 [Shortened
and
edited
version]

Symposium:
The
Current
Relevance
of
John
Maynard
Keynes
 April
1
2009
 Trinity
College,
University
of
Melbourne
 
 Included
in
the
extended
version
of
this
paper
are:
 Appendix
1:
Context
on
the
Varieties
of
Keynesianism
 Appendix
2:
Contesting
the
1930s
 Appendix
3:
The
Global
Financial
Crisis
(GFC)
 Appendix
4:
The
Blame
Game

Abstract
 
 Recent
fiscal
stimulus
packages
in
Australia
and
the
US
have
been
extensively
 criticised.
Some
grounds
are
pragmatic
(cuts
in
tax
rates
would
have
been
better
than
 cash
payments,
or
infrastructure
spending
would
have
been
better
still).
Other
 critiques
complain
that
Keynesian
policies
cannot
work
as
a
matter
of
logic.
 Defenders
of
Keynesian
policy
have
responded
to
these
criticisms.

 
 The
debate
has
been
in
the
public
arena,
so
the
deep
differences
in
the
approaches
 of
Keynesian
and
classical
economics
have
been
stated
in
plain
and
accessible
terms.
 Analogies
have
been
used
to
show
the
intuition
underlying
the
case
of
each
side.
This
 paper
strives
to
identify
the
meaning
and
significance
of
the
assumptions
made
when
 they
explain
their
positions.
Some
of
these
assumptions
are
tacit,
and
neither
side
 seems
to
be
much
aware
of
the
exaggerations
underpinning
their
confident
claims
 and
counter‐claims.
 
 This
has
been
a
rare
opportunity
to
get
into
the
minds
of
the
rivals
who
are
major
 figures
in
the
discipline.
Disagreements
about
theory
and
policy
follow
patterns,
and
 the
internal
logic
of
each
side
has
great
consistency
across
a
wide
range
of


interconnected
ideas
concerning
fiscal
deficits,
demand‐side
economics,
wealth,
 finance,
money
and
the
relationships
between
consumption,
saving
and
investment.
 For
decades
technical
economics
has
masked
these
deeper
differences
that
have
 been
long
and
deeply
debated
in
the
history
of
economic
thought
and
never
properly
 resolved.
 
 
 Dr
Bruce
Littleboy,

 School
of
Economics,

 University
of
Queensland
 b.littleboy@uq.edu.au
 
 Revised
March
31


The
Relevance
of
Keynesian
Fiscal
Policy
Today
 Extended
version
 Symposium:
The
Current
Relevance
of
John
Maynard
Keynes
 April
1
2009
 Trinity
College,
University
of
Melbourne

We
are
debating
big
ideas
and
core
principles
again.
Is
a
restoration
of
spending
crucial
to
 recovering
from
the
global
financial
crisis?
Can
fiscal
policy
work
at
all
in
raising
total
 spending?
Are
tax
cuts
more
effective
than
increases
in
government
spending?
Should
 stimulus
be
targeted,
timely
and
temporary
or
pervasive,
predictable
and
permanent?
Can
 we
afford
to
run
fiscal
deficits?
If
over‐spending
and
over‐indebtedness
got
us
into
this
mess,
 how
could
more
of
these
be
the
way
out?

 
 Until
the
last
year
or
so,
monetary
policy
has
fully
crowded
out
fiscal
policy
as
an
instrument
 of
short‐term
demand
management.
As
a
result,
recent
policy
decisions
have
been
rushed
 and
ill‐prepared.
Research
into
fiscal
policy
became
the
poor
relation.
I
conjecture
that
the
 atrophy
of
expertise
in
the
Treasury
concerning
short‐term
fiscal
policy
reflects
how
the
best
 graduates
for
years
have
gone
to
the
RBA.

 
 And
academics
bear
a
great
part
of
the
blame
for
no
longer
training
students
properly
in
 short‐term
fiscal
policy.
Indeed,
most
would
be
taught
that
it
is
ineffective
(especially
under
 flexible
exchange
rates
with
mobility
of
financial
capital),
so
it
does
not
matter
much
 whether
any
type
of
spending
is
raised
or
cut!
 
 Fiscal
policy
is
coming
back.
And
it
may
be
around
for
a
while,
if
only
because
large
stimulus
 packages
now
will
need
to
reversed
in
later
booms
by
using
fiscal
policy
rather
than
by
 relying
on
higher
interest
rates.

 
 Disagreements
about
the
potential
role
of
fiscal
policy
as
a
form
of
demand
management
 take
two
forms.
Some
are
pragmatic:
in
theory
demand
stimulus
could
work,
but
lags
and
a
 lack
of
potent
instruments
make
it
infeasible.
There
is
much
to
be
said
for
this
view.

 
 The
second
form
of
disagreement
is
the
critical
one.
Fiscal
policy
cannot
work
as
a
matter
of
 logic
and
principle.
The
deeper
intuition
here
needs
to
be
identified.
And
it
is
appropriate
to
 foreshadow
how
this
paper
argues
that
fiscal
policy
in
principle
can
work.
In
a
deep
slump,
a
 wide
and
complicated
network
of
financial
connections
has
been
disrupted
or
destroyed.
 Isolated
individuals
cannot
readily
repair
a
network.
But
a
government
can
inject
funds
to
 restore
viable,
even
if
not
optimal,
connections
simultaneously
across
the
economy.
 
 The
aim
of
current
policy
is
not
to
bring
the
economy
back
to
the
level
reached
before
the
 crisis
when
the
economy
was
likely
overheating
even
against
what
is
now
revealed
to
be
an
 unsustainable
trend.
A
damaged
financial
system
cannot
support
the
level
of
transactions
 that
were
sustainable
before.
And
many
of
the
transactions
made
before
the
crises
were
 unsustainable
anyway
(people
buying
houses
that
they
could
not
as
individuals
afford,
 consumption
based
on
asset
bubble
“wealth”
and
so
on).


Output

Former bogus trend

New sober trend

Are we here?

Big buildup of fiscal deficits occurs

Time 
 Perhaps
the
trend
will
drift
upwards
as
the
financial
sector
heals.
The
next
peak
may
be
close
 to
target.
 
 The
main
focus
here
will
be
on
fiscal
stimulus
and
its
consequences.
Budget
deficits,
 government
debt
and
national
wealth
are
interconnected.
This
paper
aims
to
remind
people
 of
the
intuition
underlying
Keynes’s
logic
or
explain
it
to
them
for
the
first
time.
We
are
not
 just
playing
academic
games
now;
ideas
matter
again.
And
many
of
these
ideas
are
old
ideas,
 the
meaning
and
significance
of
which
have
been
largely
forgotten.

 
 We
now
have
economists
and
commentators
pompously
reciting
fallacies
that
were
exposed
 decades
ago
in
texts
now
almost
forgotten.
Old
debates
and
their
modern
corollaries
are
 being
re‐argued
spiritedly;
see
for
example
the
web
debate
in
The
Economist
(2009).
 Keynesians
regard
classical
precepts
as
fallacious,
and
classical
economists
shudder
at
the
 restoration
of
overt
Keynesianism,
a
doctrine
they
thought
had
been
disproven
and
buried.

 
 All
models
simplify,
and
squeezing
the
world’s
complexities
into
these
intellectual
corsets
 will
always
leave
awkward
bulges
hanging
over.
The
line
between
the
simple
and
the
 simplistic
will
be
difficult
to
draw
deeply.
In
this
paper,
I
argue
that
a
significant
measure
of
 Keynesian
economics
is
valid.
Assertions
that
it
is
conceptually
invalid,
or
that
it
can
have
no
 beneficial
effect
in
logic,
will
be
attacked.
The
risk
is
that
I
will
over‐sell
and
present
the
 Keynesian
logic
as
self‐evidently
and
universally
valid.
 
 Science
may
not
be
a
fully
efficient
process;
the
best
knowledge
is
not
always
well
known.
 The
latest
working
paper
does
not
contain
all
the
relevant
knowledge
of
the
discipline.
While
 money
on
a
pavement
is
soon
picked
up,
good
ideas
are
often
left
lost
in
the
library.
 Systematic
error
is
possible,
and
we
may
be
very
slow
to
perceive
it.

 
 In
most
textbooks,
the
economy
is
regarded
as
a
machine.
Apply
the
correct
control
system
 and
you
will
get
the
best
outcomes
humanly
possible.
Keynesian
fiscal
fine‐tuners,
who
 would
keep
GDP
on
target,
were
replaced
in
the
1970s
and
80s
by
monetarists
who
would
 keep
the
money
supply
on
target.
And
they
were
replaced
in
the
90s
by
those
who
would


keep
inflation
on
target
by
following
a
Taylor
rule.
But
the
machine,
if
it
ever
was
one,
has
 run
amok
lately.
The
standard
levers
and
institutions
don’t
work
properly,
and
we
are
openly
 turning
again
to
Keynes.
 
 
 Have
Keynesians
Been
Hibernating
or
Hiding?
 
 Joshua
Gans
(2008)
has
asked
“How
exactly
did
Keynes
survive?”
Reading
Keynes
and
 pursuing
fiscal
stabilisation
has
essentially
disappeared
from
mainstream
US
graduate
 training.
A
Keynesian
orientation
became
a
toxic
liability
on
the
CV.
So
where
have
the
 Keynesians
sprung
from?
Most
introductory
textbooks
today
at
least
take
a
simple
Keynesian
 model
as
their
starting
point,
so
a
fragment
of
Keynesian
activism
was
saved.

 
 Perhaps
the
explanation
of
the
speed
with
which
Keynes
was
rediscovered
is
that
the
 generation
now
aged
in
their
50s,
who
are
currently
in
positions
of
influence,
was
the
last
to
 have
been
taught
this
branch
of
economics
remotely
properly.
Had
the
crisis
been
delayed
 ten
or
fifteen
years,
there
may
have
been
a
true
catastrophe.


 
 To
be
blunt,
the
Keynes
of
The
General
Theory
did
not
survive.
Only
vestiges
were
preserved
 in
the
textbooks.

Historians
of
thought
complained
long
ago
that
the
fiscal
fine‐tuning
 textbooks
around
in
the
1970s
were
poor
reflections
of
Keynes’s
writings1.
(Leijonhufvud
in
 the
1960s
rightly
referred
to
them
as
emasculated
renditions
of
Keynes.)
Animal
spirits
of
 investors,
speculation
in
bond
and
share
markets,
and
much
else
clearly
relevant
today
do
 not
fit
in
with
the
doctrine
of
efficient
markets.
Even
a
“New
Keynesian”
model
based
merely
 on
short‐term
wage‐price
inflexibility
still
simulates
fluctuations
that
can
respond
to
demand
 stimulus.
The
traditional
AE=
C+I+G+
net
exports
is
still
the
starting
point.2

 
 “Deficit”
is
a
word,
not
a
sentence.
It
triggers
moral
panic
in
many
circles,
but
Keynesians
are
 almost
blasé
about
it.
Doing
whatever
needed
to
be
done,
and
accepting
whatever
fiscal
 deficit
that
resulted
(i.e.
“functional
finance”),
was
once
publicly
acceptable,
perhaps
with
 the
contemporary
proviso
that
over
the
cycle
the
budget
should
be
balanced.
Building
 reserves
in
good
times
to
run
the
down
in
bad
times
should
make
tolerable
sense
to
any
 conservative3.
But
sound
finance
is
instinctive
for
much
of
the
populace.
Allan
Meltzer
(2009)
 wrote:
 When
Keynes
read
Abba
Lerner's
paper
on
functional
finance,
he
accepted
Lerner's
 argument
for
large
deficits,
then
he
added:
"but
heaven
help
anyone
that
tries
to
put
 it
across."
 
 It would be an interesting exercise to map the decline of the paradox of thrift, for example. Even when retained, the treatment is sometimes confusing and dismissive. Related to this is the careless treatment of what was once called the ex ante and ex post distinction, and the policy fiasco over the twin deficit hypothesis stems directly from the decay of Keynesian training. And what about government spending mostly or even fully financing itself? I wonder if anyone under 50 even knows what I’m talking about, which is my point, I suppose. 2 AE is aggregate expenditure; C is consumption spending by households; I is private-sector investment; G is government spending on currently produced goods and services, and it excludes transfer payments to households. Pensions and cash payments are regarded as reverse-flow taxes that are included in GDP only so far as households spend them (primarily on C). 3 Keynes’s words were wilder than his principal immediate policy recommendations. Luck (2009) cites Mario Rizzo’s interpretation of passages from Keynes it should be noted that bloggers have severely and validly critiqued Rizzo’s slant. See Rizzo (2009a). 1


When
two
pieces
of
common
sense
collide,
the
conventional,
the
one
introduced
earlier
and
 the
one
most
verified
in
your
personal
experience
has
the
advantage
in
debate.
Principles
of
 sound
finance
are
applicable
to
the
individual,
and
are
taken
in,
as
Keynes
once
said,
with
 one’s
mother’s
milk.
Functional
finance
still
sounds
blasphemous
to
many.

 
 Textbook
writers
looking
for
a
bulk
market
want
to
reflect
“modern
macroeconomics”
 without
wanting
to
be
confined
within
a
“school
of
thought”
or
within
a
system
with
a
wider
 social
agenda.
Phil
Bodman4
rightly
observed
that
these
textbooks
contain
Keynesian
models
 but
are
most
reluctant
to
use
the
“K
word”,
Keynes.
 
 
 The
Broad
Approach
 
 Rather
than
follow
the
over‐trodden
path
of
extracting
quotations
from
Keynes
to
strive
to
 convict
or
convince
others
of
their
doctrinal
errors
or
to
expose
misinterpretations
of
textual
 evidence,
my
goal
is
to
identify
key
ideas
and
steps
in
a
chain
of
reasoning.
As
far
as
possible,
 I
will
translate
Keynesian
teaching
into
language
that
(even)
anti‐Keynesians
should
be
able
 to
understand.
Whether
you
agree
is
not
my
concern;
my
hope
is
that
you
grasp
the
 intuition.
J.S.
Mill
(On
Liberty,
ch.2)
said,
“He
who
knows
only
his
own
side
of
the
case,
 knows
little
of
that.”


 
 The
key
ideas
of
Keynes’s
economics
are
fairly
simple,
but
Keynesians
have
delighted
in
 presenting
them
as
paradoxical,
and
this
may
have
been
a
bad
rhetorical
tactic.
(“You
have
 to
be
in
a
really
clever
minority,
like
me,
to
understand
Keynesian
economics.”)
But
simple
 truths
probably
will
sound
paradoxical
when
placed
against
conventional
half‐truths.
Most
 plausible
arguments
are
valid
in
some
domain,
and
I
hope
to
identify
expressly
some
of
what
 each
side
assumes
tacitly.
 
 This
paper
deals
with
both
the
conceptual
and
the
pragmatic
objections
to
Keynesian
 policies.
I
will
not
change
the
mind
of
anybody
committed
to
classical
economics
by
instinct
 or
by
deep
study.
I
hope
to
influence
the
emerging
position
of
the
wavering
thinker
whose
 thoughts
are
swirling
with
indecision.
 
 Many
of
the
specific,
pragmatic
objections
raised
against
proposed
stimulus
packages
make
 . significant
sense5 
The
target
of
this
paper
is
those
who
reject
attempts
at
fiscal
stimulus
on
 principle

 
 In
particular,
there
is
the
idea
that
bond‐financed
deficits
must
fully
crowd
out
other
 spending.
You
may
have
encountered
claims
that
the
government
is
scooping
a
bucket
of
 money
from
one
end
of
a
swimming
pool
and
tipping
it
into
the
other
expecting
the
water
 level
to
rise
beyond
its
starting
level.
You
may
heard
the
old
illustration
about
whether
one
 could
or
should
stimulate
the
economy
by
smashing
windows
so
that
we’ll
be
busy
repairing
 them.
Some
think
that
a
joke
or
a
metaphor
is
enough.
But
for
every
metaphor
there
is
a
 Conversation, March 5, 2009. Some objections are silly though. Lucas, in Huizinga, Murphy and Lucas (2009), wondered how fiscal policy could be tightened later on to repay the deficit. Pointing to the stimulus package involving the laying of optic cable, he joked whether the plan was to pull it up later. It got a laugh; it should have been derided. It’s a version of the “joke” that Keynesians would build hospitals in booms and close, or even demolish, them in slumps. 4 5


rejoinder.
For
example,
no
Keynesian
is
advocating
the
policy‐equivalent
of
breaking
 windows,
but,
if
they
are
already
broken,
it
makes
sense
to
repair
them.

 
 Metaphors
are
intended
to
have
didactic
value
and
to
contain
a
kernel
of
truth.
They
should
 be
taken
more
seriously
than
they
commonly
are.
They
have
rhetorical
power
and
they
 provide
insight
into
how
scientists
frame
their
explanations
of
more
complex
phenomena.
 Some
illuminate
more
exactly
than
any
formal
modelling
what
each
disputant
has
in
mind.
 They
point
to
what
is
assumed
and
to
what
causal
connections
are
held
as
dominant.
 Metaphors
can
be
overextended
and
overworked,
as
will
become
evident.
A
metaphor
that
 merely
claims
is
less
useful
than
one
that
explains.

 
 Keynesians
need
to
meet
common
sense
with
common
sense.
Suppose
someone
in
a
 meeting
says,
“Too
much
spending
and
debt
got
us
into
this
mess,
and
you
advocate
more
 borrowing
to
spend
our
way
out?!”
A
suitable
answer
may
be,
“Suppose
that
overeating
and
 lack
of
exercise
put
us
into
the
cardiac
intensive
care.
The
solution
is
not
to
pull
out
the
 tubes
and
go
jogging.
Bed
rest
is
needed
for
now.”


Or
maybe
“If
a
morphine
addict
is
 injured
and
in
pain,
it
may
be
right
to
administer
morphine.”
Or
suppose
someone
says,
 “Financial
regulation
created
the
problem,
so
it
cannot
solve
it!”
Reply:
“Botched
surgery
 may
require
more
surgery
to
fix
it
–
preferably
by
a
different
surgeon.”
These
rhetorical
 exchanges
do
have
mirror
images
in
economic
debates.
They
are
not
evasions.
 
 Here
is
how
a
Keynesian
sees
things.
Nobody
would
advocate
setting
fires
to
burn
houses
 down
to
induce
rebuilding
and
raise
GDP.
But
it
is
still
true
that
rebuilding
will
raise
GDP
and
 not
merely
crowd
out
other
spending.
There
could
be
a
bushfire‐led
recovery.
Indeed,
less
 federal
stimulus
will
be
necessary
in
view
of
the
upcoming
rebuilding
in
Victoria.6
If
 construction
workers
would
otherwise
have
been
idle
or
underemployed,
we
are
more
 prosperous
than
if
we
had
chosen
to
wring
our
hands
and
wear
sackcloth
and
ashes.
Our
 stock
of
wealth
would
be
restored,
according
to
Keynesian
reasoning,
and
GDP
would
rise
 while
we
replenish
it.

 
 The
contrary
argument
is
that
these
unemployed
workers
would
not
have
been
idle.
They
 would
be
resting,
rethinking,
relocating
and
retraining.
And
we
would
be
over‐investing
in
 houses
if
individuals
had
not
insured
them.
Recorded
GDP
figures
do
not
count
these
things
 properly.
The
apparent
short‐term
rise
in
GDP
upon
reconstruction
masks
the
reality
that
 later
GDP
will
be
lower
than
it
would
otherwise
have
been.
This
is
a
classical
argument
that
 deserves
a
hearing.
To
date,
Keynesians
have
largely
ignored
this
argument
or
have
 dismissed
it
as
absurd.
And
because
it,
in
essence,
has
recently
resurfaced
in
several
forms,
it
 requires
a
reply
–
and
perhaps
some
accommodation.

 
 Many
related
disputes
are
whirling
around.
They
need
to
be
pinned
down
in
isolation
and
 then
explained
as
connected
sets
of
ideas.
There
are
disputes
over
the
significance
of
fiscal
 deficits,
the
effects
of
changing
taxes
in
various
ways,
the
importance
of
the
distinction
 between
productive
(infrastructure)
spending
and
unproductive
consumption
(via
cash
 payments),

whether
we
should
be
consuming
to
boost
the
economy
versus
saving
to
boost
 it,

and
there
are
others.
A
fundamental
question
is
whether
one
accepts
that
markets
 overshoot
in
the
face
of
large
shocks.
If
you
cannot
accept
this,
you
do
not
regard
idle
labour
 6

Contrast the scandalous paralysis in redeveloping the Twin Towers site in New York.


or
bankrupt
firms
and
financial
institutions
as
problems.
Instead
these
are
part
of
a
healthy
 process
of
dynamic
restructuring.
It’s
quite
a
tangle,
and
I
hope
this
paper
can
sort
most
of
it
 out.
 
 
 
 Fiscal
sceptics
 
 Many
economists
of
stature
do
not
accept
that
fiscal
stimulus
is
appropriate
in
principle
or
 feasible
in
practice.
To
fund
fiscal
deficits,
existing
money
needs
to
be
borrowed
or
new
 money
created.
If
it
is
borrowed,
then
it
is
diverted
from
a
productive
alternative
use.
(This
 assertion
will
occupy
much
of
the
paper.)
Total
spending
is
unchanged,
even
if
quick
 government
spending
may
bring
some
spending
forwards.
Government
spending,
even
if
it
is
 productive
(i.e.
on
infrastructure),
crowds
out
other
spending.
(This
is
disputed
intensely.)

 Resources
used
on
government
projects
will
likely
be
diverted
from
an
alternative
and
 private
use.
Furthermore,
government
projects
are
likely
to
be
managed
less
efficiently
than
 private
ones.
(Sensible,
but
this
is
not
open‐and‐shut
case.)
As
these
resources
are
also
being
 diverted
from
a
more
valuable
use,
our
wealth
is
less
than
it
would
otherwise
have
been.
 (This
analysis
is
disputed
in
the
next
section.)
 
 If
the
outlays
promote
consumption
(e.g.,
lump‐sum
tax
cuts,
or
cash
transfer
payments),
 then
nothing
is
left
behind
after
the
spending
except
the
deficit.
And
rational
taxpayers
will
 realise
that
payments
now
will
need
to
be
recouped
by
the
government
in
the
form
of
higher
 taxes
later.
So
this
means
that
many
will
save
the
payments
to
meet
the
future
tax
burden.
 (This
is
based
on
what
is
called
Ricardian
equivalence,
something
I
had
thought
was
regarded
 as
discredited
long
ago.)

 
 It
may
be
a
better
idea
to
have
“permanent”
(this
term
is
explored
later)
cuts
in
marginal
 rates
of
taxation.
Disposable
income
not
only
rises
for
a
period
long
enough
to
encourage
 consumption,
there
is
also
a
supply‐side
stimulus
in
that
people
have
greater
incentives
to
 work
and
invest.
Current
fiscal
packages
omit
the
only
measures
that
are
likely
to
be
 beneficial.
 
 When
the
stimulus
(if
any)
stops,
we’d
revert
anyway,
so
what’s
the
point
of
a
“temporary”
 stimulus?
(This
simply
fails
to
grasp
what
is
meant
by
pump‐priming.
If
a
recovery
can
be
 hastened
by
timely
pre‐emptive
policy,
private‐sector
confidence
returns
and
the
 government
activity
can
quietly
recede.)
Clearly
the
critics
of
fiscal
policy
are
baffled
by
the
 widespread
academic
and
expert
acceptance
of
fiscal
stimulus.

 
 If
deficits
are
funded
by
printing
money,
then
any
stimulus
is
really
attributable
to
monetary
 policy,
according
to
the
fiscal
sceptics.
And
monetary
stimulus
risks
imminent
or
subsequent
 inflation
that
can
only
be
prevented
by
severe
monetary
tightening
later
on.
The
slump
is
 just
being
shifted
through
time.
(At
the
risk
of
trivialising
what
is
a
significant
difficulty,
this
is
 a
technical
matter
that
later
monetary
and
fiscal
policymakers
will
need
to
discuss
soon
in
 order
to
be
well
prepared
prevent
a
slump
down
the
track.)
If
a
government
is
trying
to


appropriate
resources
beyond
the
country's
sustainable
capacity
to
supply,
fine,
later
 inflation
erodes
the
real
value
of
the
government
debt.
During
a
slump,
this
not
an
issue7.

 
 In
the
Australian
context,
it
is
not
unfair
to
focus
on
people
who
have
made
a
point
of
openly
 opposing
the
stimulus
package
partly
along
lines
similar
to
the
points
made
above:
see
Ergas
 (2009),
Kates
(2009a:
2009b)
and
Makin
(2009a;
2009b).
There
are
real
differences
in
nuance
 and
degree,
but
their
contributions
dovetail.
Some
of
their
reasons
are
based
on
practical
 grounds,
and
I
share
some
of
these
misgivings,
but
the
thrust
of
their
objections
is
 conceptual
and
theoretical.
Fiscal
stimulus
is
close
to
oxymoronic
in
the
eyes
of
its
circle
of
 hardline
critics.

 
 
 Deficit
attention
disorder?
 
 Here
is
a
broad
reply
to
the
points
above
outlined
as
criticisms
of
spending
packages.
Why
 do
Keynesians
worry
rather
less
about
fiscal
deficits
than
just
about
everybody
else?
We
do
 partly
because
of
experience.
At
the
end
of
World
War
2,
the
ratio
of
government
debt
to
 GDP
in
the
US,
Britain
and
Australia
was
around
1.7
to
2.4;
i.e.,
around
double
GDP.

 
 
 Budget
Deficit
as
a
Percent
of
GDP

Source:
US
Congressional
Budget
Office,
via
Mankiw
(2009)

Is
this
relevant
here?
 Efforts
made
in
Australia
to
paint
an
extrapolated
figure
of
20%
as
a
severe
burden
on
future
 generations
of
taxpayers
would
appear
to
be
over‐statements.
Had
economists
urged
us
to
 surrender
to
the
Japanese
to
prevent
an
excessive
national
debt,
we
would
have
called
this
 treason.
But
we
are
being
urged
now
to
hold
our
fiscal
ammunition
back
as
though
it
was
in
 tight
supply.
 
 Contrary
to
conservatives
writing
in
the
tradition
of
classical
economics,
full‐strength
 Keynesians
would
argue
that
we
and
our
children
will
gain
from
our
recent
fiscal
deficits.
The
 relationship
between
fiscal
deficits
and
the
generation
of
wealth
and
income
clearly
require
 discussion.
What
follows
is
a
Keynesian
critique
of
the
classical
position
that
is
championed
 in
the
Chicago
Circle
and
by
members
of
the
Austrian
School.
 
 There
is
a
gigantic
difference
between
what
is
true
when
resources
are
idle
in
a
slump
and
 when
resources
are
already
in
efficient
use.
In
the
former
case
we
can
sustainably
produce
 more
of
everything.
In
the
latter,
more
of
one
thing
must
come
at
the
expense
of
something
 else.
This
idea
impacts
on
how
we
should
evaluate
the
effects
of
fiscal
stimulus
on
wealth,
 In particular, stagflation is a scenario to consider, but outcomes in 1970s drew somewhat from the different institutional context prevailing then. 7


indebtedness
and
income.
As
there
is
idle
capacity,
recent
increases
in
government
outlays
 in
Australia
will
not
be
a
burden,
regardless
of
whether
it
is
devoted
to
investment
or
to
 consumption.
 
 Our
problem
now
is
not
our
lack
of
productive
capacity.
Our
problem
is
that
we
are
unable
 to
use
the
capacity
we
already
have.
So
the
fundamental
solution
is
not
more
infrastructure,
 lower
tax
rates
or
greater
labour
market
flexibility
to
boost
supply.
These
things
may
be
 useful
and
desirable
to
a
point,
but
they
are
not
essential
to
what
needs
to
be
done.

 
 It
is
true
that
by
increasing
our
long‐term
productive
capacity,
investment
will
enhance
our
 national
wealth
more
than
consumption
would.
Greater
supply
makes
debt
easier
to
deal
 with
too,
but
increased
government
debt
need
not
deter
us
from
greater
household
 consumption
as
a
temporary
stimulus.
Consumption
does
not
send
us
backwards;
it
carries
 us
forwards
out
of
a
slump,
in
terms
of
income
earned,
much
as
capital
investment
would.
 But
capital
indeed
is
still
there
after
the
slump
has
passed.
The
usefulness
or
otherwise
of
 government
infrastructure
spending
is
discussed
elsewhere.
 
 Our
wealth
is
our
ability
to
produce.
If
resources
are
left
idle,
output
is
lost
forever.
It
is
not
 stored
up
for
later
use.
It
is
therefore
better
to
produce
and
consume
now
than
not
to
 produce
at
all.
Compared
to
producing
nothing,
more
consumption
spending
does
raise
GDP.
 This
is
true
when
idle
resources
can
sustainably
be
re‐employed
by
the
restoration
of
 demand.
Of
course,
the
situation
is
different
if
wasteful
spending
causes
an
economy
to
 overheat.

 
 Low
demand
today
reduces
the
incentive
to
invest
today.
Less
investment
today
means
less
 capital
exists
tomorrow
for
our
children.
Both
consumption
and
investment
can
rise
if
idle
 resources
are
available.
Production
and
income
today
need
not
reduce
production
and
 income
tomorrow.

 
 Though
production
and
spending
may
recently
have
overshot
what
we
now
realise
is
 sustainable
over
the
trend,
we
are
not
currently
in
much
danger
of
crossing
the
line
into
 overheating.
The
task
now
is
to
minimise
the
extent
to
which
markets
will
overshoot
in
the
 direction
of
contraction.
At
best,
the
concerns
expressed
by
Makin
about
the
need
for
IMF‐ imposed
fiscal
discipline
apply
only
to
lesser
developed
countries
over‐working
a
limited
 trend
capacity
to
produce.
They
are
irrelevant
to
Australia’s
situation,
and
this
IMF‐think
 should
be
flicked
aside.
 
 Finance
coordinates
the
transition
of
inputs
into
output.
It
is
the
economy’s
signal
bearer.
 Buyers
tell
sellers
what
they
want
them
to
produce
by
offering
to
pay
money.
The
healthy
 circulation
of
funds
is
vital.
Without
oil
exactly
where
it
is
needed,
an
engine
seizes
up.
Too
 little
money,
credit
and
debt
are
bad
because
resources
will
be
idle
as
a
result.
Too
much
 finance
is
bad
if
output
and
spending
are
unsustainably
high.
 
 Deficits
and
debt
activate
wealth
when
they
enable
greater
sustainable
production.
Wealth
 is
more
than
our
available
land,
labour,
capital
and
technology.
These
resources
must
be
 financially
coordinated
so
that
output
occurs.


If
our
capacity
is
permanently
idle,
it
would
not
count
as
wealth
at
all.
It
may
be
wealth
in
 some
notional
and
hypothetical
sense,
but
it
would
not
be
wealth
in
any
effective
sense.
 Inactive
capacity
is
less
valuable
than
active
capacity.
Wealth
rises
when
it
is
used.
In
a
 slump,
a
rise
in
effective
demand
raises
effective
wealth.8
 
 We
cannot
afford
to
avoid
debt,
if
debt
is
needed
to
keep
our
current
potential
capacity
in
 production.
In
1942
Keynes
(CW
XXVII,
p.
272)
rightly
said,
“anything
we
can
actually
do
we
 can
afford”.

If
all
the
resources
are
just
sitting
there
going
to
waste,
it
is
silly
not
to
use
them
 instead.
If
the
only
thing
holding
production
back
is
a
temporary
reduction
in
demand,
then
 raise
demand
back
towards
a
sustainable
level.
 
 Employment
preserves
human
capital
and
lessens
de‐skilling
and
demoralisation.
As
people
 learn
by
doing,
ongoing
employment
avoids
“forgetting
by
not
doing”.
Systems
do
not
spring
 back
into
shape
if
the
short‐term
shock
inflicts
long‐term
damage,
and
this
is
known
as
 hysteresis.
Relying
on
automatic
market‐led
recovery
is
even
more
problematic
if
the
shock
 attacks
the
system’s
very
capacity
to
recover.
Market
dynamics
are
not
optimal
and
they
 may
be
improved
upon.

 
 If
the
resulting
fiscal
deficits
are
funded
by
bond
sales,
taxpayers
eventually
bear
the
burden
 of
their
repayment.
But
taxpayers
also
directly
or
indirectly
own
the
bonds.
We
are
paying
 money
to
ourselves,
and
there
is
no
net
burden.9
During
later
years
of
overheating,
the
 government
should
sternly
impose
surpluses
and
suck
out
the
excess
money
and
bonds.
This
 is
a
rather
silly‐looking
piece
of
paper
churning10
taking
years,
and
there
may
be
a
better
way
 of
doing
things.
But
it
places
no
great
burden
on
the
economy,
just
on
officials
at
the
 Treasury
and
the
RBA.
Preaching
about
the
sinfulness
of
debt
is
Sunday
school
economics.

 
 Fiscal
deficits
have
two
sources.
A
decline
in
income
automatically
reduces
the
tax
harvest
 and
creates
a
deficit.
Even
the
Federal
Opposition
tacitly
accepts
that
these
deficits
are
 necessary.
The
fiscal
tide
will
turn
later.
Although
these
deficits
reduce
the
size
of
the
 downturn,
they
impart
no
fiscal
thrust
to
push
the
economy
back
to
a
higher
sustainable
 position.
Second,
there
are
policy
decisions
to
change
government
spending,
welfare
 eligibility
and
taxation
scales.
These
impart
active
fiscal
stimulus.
They
increase
what
 economists
call
the
structural
fiscal
deficit.
The
only
questions
then
are
how
much
and
what
 type
of
stimulus.
I
return
to
this
issue
later
in
the
paper.
 
 Tony
Makin
is
concerned
that
government
outlays
already
over‐fund
private
consumption.
If
 payouts
to
foster
consumption
are
so
bad,
we
all
should
be
much
more
concerned
than
we
 are
about
the
mega‐dollars
already
spent
on
middle
class
welfare.
But
note
that
each
outlay
 dollar
that
funds
consumption
contributes
equally
to
a
fiscal
deficit.
The
last
ones
on
board
 from
the
December
and
February
packages
are
no
more
inherently
pernicious
or
virtuous
 Share prices rise, for example, as expected profits rise during recovery. The distinction between notional and effective is made in the works of Clower and Leijonhufvud, who are mentioned in Appendix 1. I have extended the distinction into the domain of wealth. 9 Some of the debt will be owned by foreigners, it is true. The world is a closed economy, so if all governments increase the borrowings to fund deficits. But if all governments issue bonds in proportion to their GDP, this broadly cancels out. We earthlings owe it to ourselves. (Besides, the Martians aren’t silly enough to lend to us.) The peculiar imbalance between China’s high saving and the USA’s consumption is globally important but is not much relevant to fiscal policy settings in Australia. 10 It is made even sillier-looking by the simultaneous massive increases in base money to prop up the balance sheets of the private banks. 8


than
the
earlier
ones.
As
economists
know,
money
is
fungible.
But
Makin
is
right
about
 cutting
ineffective
and
inequitable
middle‐class
welfare
spending,
provided
he
proposes
to
 replace
it
immediately
with
something
fairer
and
more
effective
in
boosting
short‐term
 demand.

 
 Wasteful
spending
simply
sounds
bad.
It
suggests
that
the
economy
could
even
go
 backwards.
To
put
popular
speech
into
unpopular
jargon,
wouldn’t
the
multiplier
be
zero
or
 even
negative?

But
what
do
we
mean
by
“wasteful”?
Do
we
merely
mean
that
resources
 could
have
been
put
to
even
better
use
and
that
a
better
opportunity
was
forgone?
Do
we
 mean
that
it
would
have
been
better
to
keep
the
resource
stocks
unused
now
for
a
better
 use
later?
This
makes
sense
for
a
reservoir
of
oil,
but
the
productive
capacities
of
capital
and
 labour
are
flows
that
cannot
be
stored
in
any
significant
way.
Better
to
consume
more
 output
now
than
to
have
nothing
at
all
now
and
in
the
future
too.
 
 Consumption
itself
is
not
wealth,
of
course.
It
directly
uses
up
existing
wealth
in
so
far
as
 capital
wears
out
when
producing
consumption
goods.
A
higher
trend
share
of
consumption
 from
full‐capacity
output
reduces
the
trend
investment
share
and
this
reduces
wealth,
other
 things
equal.
In
this
case
consumption
now
comes
at
the
expense
of
more
consumption
 later.
But
present
consumption
might
encourage
firms
to
increase
capacity,
and
it
is
the
 latter
that
constitutes
wealth.
Consumption
and
investment
are
therefore
complements
as
 well
as
substitutes.
Consumption
might
also
reactivate
idle
resources,
especially
during
 slumps.
Idleness
reduces
quality
of
resources
and
therefore
the
effective
value
of
productive
 wealth.
The
effect
of
consumption
on
wealth
therefore
is
indirect
and
not
generalisable.
 
 In
one
case
though,
Keynes’s
rhetorical
flair
got
the
better
of
him11:
 
 During
a
1934
dinner
in
the
U.S.,
after
one
economist
carefully
removed
a
towel
from
 a
stack
to
dry
his
hands,
Mr.
Keynes
swept
the
whole
pile
of
towels
on
the
floor
and
 crumpled
them
up,
explaining
that
his
way
of
using
towels
did
more
to
stimulate
 employment
among
restaurant
workers.
[See
Reddy
(2009).]
 
 This
only
makes
sense
if
Maynard
is
sent
the
bill
and
pays
it.
Raising
the
private
costs
of
 doing
business
without
raising
demand
(revenue)
by
at
least
as
much
does
no
good.

 Of
course
greater
consumption
may
increase
short‐term
income
and
total
output,
as
distinct
 from
increasing
the
wealth
underpinning
the
economy’s
current
potential
capacity
to
 supply12.
And
consumption
can
erode
wealth
(partying
away
your
life
savings,
or
chopping
 down
trees
to
make
confetti).
As
measured
in
the
national
accounts,
consumption
raises
 GDP
if
output
rises.
But
sometimes
we
in
effect
consume
our
capital
(our
stock
of
wealth)
 and
misleadingly
define
this
as
higher
income.
 Infrastructure
(capital)
spending
tends
to
find
greater
political
and
academic
support,
partly
 because
they
may
be
financially
viable
from
an
accounting
viewpoint.
User
charges
may
be
 Steve Kates has also criticised Keynes here, but this example in fact rather poorly explains what Keynes meant. It was a carelessly chosen metaphor. 12 Potential capacity is what the economy could sustainably produce, given the quantity and quality of its resources, the state of technology and the framework of institutions, laws, taxation and culture. The current value of potential supply is crudely approximated by the trend line through observed output. Of course, the willingness and ability to supply may be affected by changes in technology, rates of taxation or microeconomic reform. Keynesians argue that these factors change fairly slowly, so trend output is a sensible approximation. 11


levied,
or
firm’s
will
face
lower
production
costs
and
be
able
to
pay
the
taxes
required
to
 repay
the
debt
incurred.
By
contrast,
“unproductive”
consumption
spending
certainly
 triggers
an
almost
visceral
sense
of
distrust
and
revulsion.
 
 Perhaps
normative
concerns
about
the
immorality
of
debt
are
still
entangled
in
debates
over
 fiscal
deficits.
This
is
often
combined
with
another
moral
panic
about
supporting
 consumption
without
work.
The
undeserving
poor
should
not
be
given
money:
they’ll
just
 spend
it
(on
plasma
TVs
and
pokies)
and
there’ll
be
nothing
to
show.
But
Sunday
School
 Economics
is
a
politically
potent
opponent
of
Keynesian
economics.
 
 Is
funding
the
deficit
a
problem?
 Why
do
critics
of
fiscal
stimulus
believe
that
people
won’t
buy
the
large
volume
of
bonds
to
 fund
a
series
of
deficits?
(I
put
aside
the
extra
funds
devoted
merely
to
prop
up
financial
 institutions.)
Some
argue
that
big
deficits
will
drive
up
interest
rates
to
make
buying
these
 bonds
attractive,
and
higher
interest
rates
will
contract
the
economy.

 
 We
know
that
this
is
wrong,
generally
speaking.
When
private‐sector
spending
 autonomously
declines,
a
slump
may
occur.
Inflation
falls
in
a
slump,
so
central
banks
cut
 interest
rates
to
below
average
levels.
Interest
rates
in
slumps
are
lower
than
they
are
in
 booms
(the
important
exception
being
when
a
central
bank
raises
interest
rates
to
disinflate
 the
economy
and
thereby
create
a
recession).
During
slumps,
large
deficits
emerge.
Large
 deficits
are
therefore
associated
with
low
interest
rates.

 
 Neither
does
active
fiscal
stimulus
raise
interest
rates
in
modern
monetary
regimes.
Only
if
 the
economy
is
overheated
through
ill‐judged
fiscal
stimulus
would
inflation
rise.
Innocently
 Ergas
(see
2009a)
trusts
the
textbooks.
The
old
argument
was
that
fiscal
stimulus,
under
 flexible
exchange
rates
and
with
mobile
financial
capital,
would
raise
interest
rates,
 strengthen
the
domestic
currency,
reduce
net
exports
and
this
would
offset
the
stimulus.
 But
these
days
interest
rates
would
remain
unchanged
until
there
were
fears
of
overheating.

 
 Aside
from
being
irrelevant
under
modern
central
banking
regimes,
the
logic
itself
is
patently
 bizarre.
It
would
equally
imply
that
contractionary
policy
would
have
no
effect
on
total
 spending.
Even
more
absurdly,
it
implies
that
no
change
in
any
component
in
spending
can
 change
total
spending.
Stronger
demand
by
households,
firms
and
even
foreigners
would
 supposedly
raise
interest
rates
and
thereby
soon
crowd
out
the
extra
private
spending.

 
 Textbooks13
have
also
confused
matters
by
failing
to
distinguish
short‐term
from
long‐term
 behaviour.
Over
the
trend,
by
contrast,
sustained
fiscal
stimulus
raises
interest
rates
by
 creating
excessive
spending
growth
compared
to
the
growth
in
productive
capacity.

 
 The
second
concern
about
fiscal
deficits
is
that
they
eventually
get
monetised,
and
this
 causes
inflation.
This
is
a
problem
for
the
future
that
needs
to
be
addressed,
and
it
is
 discussed
later.
Governments
are
at
least
making
noises
about
the
need
to
raise
surpluses
 later
to
repay
debt.
This
is
a
responsible
course
only
after
the
economy
has
fully
recovered
 and
is
overheating.
It
may
take
a
few
small
booms
to
recoup
the
deficits
created
in
a
deep

13

An exception is Littleboy and Taylor (2005; 2009).


slump,
and
the
time
frame
could
be
one
or
two
decades.
Monetary
policy
may
need
to
take
 a
holiday
for
quite
a
while
from
being
the
main
weapon
against
fluctuations
in
inflation.
 
 Third,
the
deficits
are
so
large
that
governments
will
default
–
see
Buiter
(2009)
–
but
this
is
 not
relevant
to
Australia.
The
US
and
UK
may
be
in
greater
danger
of
a
lack
of
public
 (actually,
I
may
probably
just
mean
“market”!)
trust
and
lack
of
credibility14.

 
 Another
problem,
I
think,
is
that
these
new
bonds
are
sold
when
interest
rates
have
 bottomed.
When
interest
rates
rise
later
in
the
cycle,
holders
make
a
capital
loss
on
the
 bonds
they’ve
bought
at
such
low
yields.
This
strikes
me
as
a
more
plausible
reason
not
to
 buy
long‐term
bonds
than
concerns
over
sovereign
default
or
the
later
inflation
risk
as
the
 debt
matures.
It
is
not
clear
(to
me)
why
governments
do
not
offer
variable‐rate
bonds
as
 part
of
the
suite,
offering
the
average
annual
overnight
cash
rate
plus
x%.

Selling
inflation‐ indexed
bonds
also
may
ease
anxieties
that
some
buyers
might
have.

 Keynesians,
especially
old‐style
hardliners,
are
dismissive
of
concerns
about
deficits.
They
 are
pretty
harmless;
besides,
they
may
mostly
be
transitory.


 This
standard
Keynesian
position
is
put
by
Krugman
(2009):

In
this
picture
savings
plus
taxes
equal
investment
plus
government
spending,
the
 accounting
identity
that
both
Fama
and
Cochrane
think
vitiates
fiscal
policy
—
but
it
 doesn’t.
An
increase
in
G
doesn’t
reduce
I
one
for
one,
it
increases
GDP,
which
leads
 to
higher
S
and
T.

This
sounds
too
good
to
be
true15,
and
there
is
a
catch.
The
increase
in
G
is
soon
self‐funding
 as
shown
above,
but
there
is
still
the
matter
of
covering
the
cyclical
deficit
created
by
the
 slump
itself.
For
this,
there
will
need
to
be
subsequent
booms
to
generate
cyclical
fiscal
 windfalls.
However
the
fiscal
stimulus
does
fund
itself,
so
a
large
part
of
the
total
(global)
 debt
should
soon
disappear.16

This
comforting
conclusion
also
stems
from
the
key
 assumption
that
investment
is
autonomous,
unaffected
by
the
higher
G.
There
is
neither
 crowding
out
nor
crowding
in
(the
latter
referring
to
how
infrastructure
spending
may
 Buiter (2009) argues that the US and the UK lack fiscal credibility already. Ergas (2009) dismisses this as nonsense on stilts, but provides no reasoning, except perhaps the idea that government spending is wasting resources that were going to be put to a better use soon anyway. 16 The extra saving and taxation generated in the restoration of GDP to trend recoups either the new structural (the stimulus) component of the deficit or the existing cyclical (automatic stabilisation) component of the deficit, but not both. To repay both, you need a boom (or a few smaller booms) as big as the current slump, and in practice this could take a decade of fiscal discipline or rather more to claw back. But a big chunk (half) of the deficit would quickly be self-funding. 14

15


promote
investment
or
that
successful
pump‐priming
can
restore
investor
confidence).
 Crowding
out
requires
separate
attention.
 
 
 
 Problems
multiplying
 
 If
fiscal
stimulus
is
regarded
as
necessary,
is
greater
government
spending
better
than
tax
 cuts?
Is
government
spending
is
likely
in
practice
to
deliver
the
stimulus
promised?
Even
if
 governments
invest
in
infrastructure
rather
than
promote
consumption,
will
total
spending,
 output
and
employment
respond
as
hoped?
 
 Two
concerns
about
the
efficacy
of
fiscal
policy
relate
to
the
size
of
the
fiscal
multiplier
for
 government
spending.
First,
crowding
out
reduces
the
stimulus
resulting
from
the
injection
if
 the
extra
government
spending
literally
took
resources
away
from
imminent
use
by
the
 private
sector.
The
second
concern
is
that
the
multiplier
depends
on
the
size
of
induced
 consumption.
If
people
earn
more
income
from
a
government
project,
how
much
will
they
 spend
on
consumption?
 
 1.
Crowding
out
 
 When
resources
are
in
tight
supply,
as
they
may
be
in
some
sectors
of
the
economy
at
any
 time,
multipliers
are
low
and
demand
stimulus
there
is
inappropriate
anyway.
Empirical
 studies
on
fiscal
policy
tell
us
little
if
data
is
collected
at
all
phases
of
the
cycle
and
cases
 where
the
timing
and
size
of
stimulus
were
faulty
are
included.
What
we
would
like
to
know
 is
the
size
of
the
multiplier
in
slumps
when
fiscal
policy
is
clearly
warranted.

 
 Keynesians
note
that
a
possible
advantage
of
government
spending
is
that
it
can
also
be
 directed
to
industries
and
to
regions
most
affected
by
the
downturn
in
total
spending.
 Crowding
out
is
not
an
issue
where
resources
are
patently
idle.
But
conservative
classical
 economists
challenge
this
rationale
too
on
the
grounds
that
important
structural
distortions
 occur
in
practice
regardless
of
the
form
of
government
spending.

 
 Basic
Keynesian
models
do
assume
that
labour
and
capital
are
homogeneous
aggregates,
so
 the
model
discounts
the
very
possibility
of
supply
bottlenecks.
If
unemployment
is
 widespread
and
substantial,
an
elastic
supply
response
is
reasonable.
Keynesians
are
rather
 blasé
about
micro‐structural
concerns
and
they
regard
these
constraints
as
small
enough
to
 ignore
in
practice.
(We
return
to
this
later.)
 
 But
domestic
multipliers
would
be
higher,
if
expenditure
programs
are
properly
targeted
 towards
industries
with
idle
capacity
and
with
a
substantial
contribution
of
domestic
inputs.
 And
they
would
be
if
fiscal
policy
was
conducted
in
a
professional
manner
instead
of
being
 improvised
in
desperate
haste.
But
even
this
feature
of
skilled
fiscal
policy‐making
has
its
 critics
(the
usual
suspects).
 
 Becker
(2009)
provides
an
argument
against
the
specifics
of
the
Obama
package,
and
he
 maintains
that
crowding
out
occurs
in
many
cases.
The
supply
of
already
scarce
health
care
 workers
cannot
much
respond
to
increases
in
government
spending
on
health.


This
same
conclusion
applies
to
spending
on
expanding
broadband,
to
make
the
 energy
used
greener,
to
encourage
new
technologies
and
more
research,
and
to
 improve
teaching.

 If
Becker
is
right,
the
fiscal
stimulus
will
be
weak.
This
is
an
empirical
question
and
a
matter
 of
degree.
But
one
may
concede
that
in
a
modern
world
fiscal
stimulus
is
trickier
than
in
the
 1930s.
Back
then,
unemployed
ship
builders
could
switch
from
cargo
ships
to
battle
ships.
In
 the
1930s,
one
could
replace
the
private
demand
for
steel
with
government
demand
 (Hoover
dam,
battleships).
Today,
governments
cannot
really
buy
coal
and
iron
ore
to
make
 up
for
the
missing
exports
to
China
and
Japan.
Although
there
also
was
a
financial
crisis
in
 the
1930s,
I
doubt
that
standard
Keynesian
remedies
are
as
fully
applicable
today.
 A
more
obstinate
objection
to
fiscal
stimulus
is
provided
by
John
Huizinga,
Robert
Lucas
and
Kevin
Murphy
 (2009).
Don’t
hire
construction
workers
who
formerly
worked
in
the
over‐sized
housing
 industry.
Let
them
exit
the
construction
industry
instead.
Markets
are
telling
them
to
exit.

 
 But
are
markets
sending
true
signals?
Axel
Leijonhufvud
(1968)
stressed
that
a
lack
of
 effective
demand
falsely
signals
agents
that
purchasers
don’t
want
their
products.
They
do,
 but
if
there
is
involuntary
unemployment
and
a
contraction
of
spending,
these
signals
are
 perverse
and
false.
When
markets
go
haywire,
false
signals
spew
out.
Markets
mal‐ coordinate
when
disturbed
by
shocks
that
are
too
large
quickly
to
absorb
or
neutralise.
If
 demand
is
restored,
true
signals
are
restored
too.
Macrostructural
shocks
may
require
fiscal
 stimulus
so
that
the
resources
rendered
idle
will
more
smoothly
find
a
new
use
elsewhere.
 
 The
upshot
is
that
Chicago
economics
brazenly
says
that
greater
government
spending
 should
not
occur
in
industries
either
facing
labour
shortages
or
experiencing
substantial
 unemployment.
 
 Aggregate
demand
shocks
in
reality
are
not
spread
remotely
evenly
across
the
affected
 sectors.
The
income
elasticity
of
demand
differs
between
products,
and
things
that
are
less
 necessary
(buying
new
durables,
dining
out,
buying
flowers
etc.)
will
be
cut
 disproportionately.
There
is
always
a
seemingly
structural
impact.

 
 The
dispute
centres
on
the
weight
placed
on
macro‐aggregates
versus
efficient
micro‐ allocation.
Is
total
employment
the
primary
target
total
or
is
getting
the
right
composition
of
 employment
more
important?
Keynes
(1936,
ch.
24)
felt
that
markets
did
a
good
enough
job
 with
the
latter,
but
it
is
impossible
in
practice
to
alter
total
employment
without
for
a
time
 affecting
the
composition.

 
 Keynesians
would
concede
that
there
is
sometimes
a
vague
line
between
structurally
 targeted
stimulus
and
outright
bail‐outs.
Economists
are
not
fans
of
propping
up
industries
 that
merely
have
political
lobbying
power.
Why
support
dying
industries,
or
ones
with
 chronic
global
oversupply?

Even
if
one
rejects
industry
supports,
a
general
environment
of
 fiscal
stimulus
is
conducive
to
transition.17
Structural
adjustment
only
occurs
if
there
is
an
 effective
excess
demand
for
the
goods
that
will
replace
the
old.
Phase‐out
is
better
than
bail‐ out.
Employment
levels
are
governed
both
by
jobs
being
created
and
jobs
being
saved.

 
 17

This is another extension of the economics of Leijonhufvud.


The
strength
of
induced
consumption
 
 The
standard
Keynesian
story
is
that
households
fairly
reliably
spend
the
bulk
of
extra
 income
earned.
A
worker
employed
to
build
a
road
will
buy
groceries.
The
retail
sector
will
 obtain
more
revenue
and
the
fiscal
stimulus
will
ripple
through
the
economy.

 And
if
the
worker
mostly
bought
imports,
the
expenditure
would
son
leak
out
of
the
 domestic
expenditure
flow.
Just
as
bad,
diverse
and
widespread
anxieties
would
encourage
 saving
rather
than
consumption,
possibly
the
hoarding
of
funds
in
mattresses.
 
 Since
the
1930s,
consumption
patterns
have
changed.
Nowadays
much
spending
is
 discretionary,
and
it
is
driven
by
peer
pressure
and
status
rather
than
by
physical
need.
 Consumer
durables
are
more
important,
and
these
can
be
deferred.
Provided
funds
are
 targeted
to
the
cash‐constrained,
the
marginal
propensity
to
spend
is
likely
still
to
be
high.
In
 the
1930s
one
could
rely
on
the
many
desperate,
liquidity‐constrained
people
spending
 extra
income
on
necessities.
If
people
were
hungry,
you
know
that
they
would
buy
food
 most
of
which
would
be
produced
locally.

 
 Standard
Keynesian
models
warn
us
that
open
economy
multipliers
may
be
much
smaller
 than
the
closed
economy
multiplier,
especially
as
the
domestic
marginal
propensity
to
 import
may
be
high
(plasma
TVs,
mobile
phones,
computers
etc.).


 
 So
far
as
the
potential
power
of
fiscal
stimulus
is
concerned,
what
is
the
multiplier
likely
to
 be
during
a
global
slump?
The
globe
is
a
closed
economy.
There
is
no
leakage
of
imports,
so
 the
global
multiplier
will
exceed
the
multiplier
of
an
average
individual
nation.
If
all
 governments
apply
stimulus,
what
leaks
out
from
Australia
is
on
average
matched
by
foreign
 stimulus
that
is
injected
here.
Talk
of
multipliers
being
small18
and
usually
lying
between
0.6
 and
1
only
indicates
the
scale
of
our
profession’s
misunderstanding.
If
there
is
concerted
 stimulus,
will
econometricians
attribute
extra
exports
from
A
to
the
fiscal
expansion
of
B?

 
 In
the
case
of
a
global
slump
and
a
global
stimulus,
the
import
leakage
would
cease
to
be
an
 issue,
of
course,
though,
if
fiscal
stimulus
is
practices
unevenly,
import
leakages
will
be
an
 issue
in
some
countries.
This
is
one
reason
why
the
US
is
lobbying
the
EU
to
increase
fiscal
 stimulus,
but,
under
the
guise
of
fiscal
prudence,
the
Europeans
are
practising
beggar‐thy‐ neighbour
policies
and
hoping
to
free
ride
on
the
American
stimulus
to
global
spending.

 
 
 Say
again?

According
to
John
Cochrane
(Chicago)
during
the
Economist’s
web
debate:
 Robert
Barro's
Ricardian
equivalence
[RE]
theorem
was
one
nail
in
the
coffin.
This
 theorem
says
that
stimulus
[via
lump‐sum
tax
cuts,
strictly
speaking]
cannot
work
 because
people
know
their
taxes
must
rise
in
the
future.

“The” multiplier as measured by econometricians is often a sludge average of untargeted policies across the cycle commonly initiated for purposes unrelated to macro-stimulus You may need to watch whether they strip out the effects of money-financed G and call it monetary policy. 18


Tony
Makin
(2009b)
also
takes
this
argument
seriously.
Many
do
not.
If
people
are
not
 spending
much
of
their
cash
payments,
higher
precautionary
saving
(including
debt
 repayments)
would
be
a
more
likely
explanation.
 
 The
point
of
RE
is
that
forward‐looking
people
won’t
spend
a
tax‐cut
if
they
believe
that
it
 will
later
be
reversed
and
the
funds
returned
(with
interest)
to
repay
the
fiscal
debt.
Few
 outside
Chicago
are
convinced
that
RE
is
much
relevant
to
reality,
today
or
ever.
Are
people
 so
forward
looking
and
well‐informed?
Liquidity
constraints
and
involuntary
unemployment
 are
possible,
and
people
thus
affected
will
spend
on
the
basis
of
their
frustrated
pent‐up
 demand.
But
New
Classical
Economics
(its
modern
mantle
is
equilibrium
real
business
cycle
 theory)
assumes
that
markets
optimise.
 
 One
wonders
whether
Barro
is
aware
of
Say’s
Law
and
any
sense
in
which
he
relies
on
it.
 Continuous
market
clearing
is
a
long
way
from
Say
who
wrote
about
derangements,
 distortions
and
dislocations
of
supply.
About
all
they
share
is
a
willingness
to
blame
 governments
for
shortcomings
in
market
performance.
The
history
of
economic
thought,
 classical
or
Keynesian
is
not
Barro’s
strongpoint.
Ricardo
himself
rejected
Ricardian
 Equivalence,
according
to
O’Driscoll
(1997)
19.
 
 Say’s
Law
points
to
the
powerful
insight
that
economic
exchange
is
precisely
that:
exchange.
 All
parties
to
the
exchange
needs
to
supply
a
good
or
service
wanted
by
the
other(s).
 Production
involves
a
complex
series
of
exchanges
through
time.
But
often
more
is
read
into
 this
insight
than
is
warranted.
In
particular,
there
are
recurring
fallacies
that
refuse
to
die.
 Stakes
in
hand
yet
again,
let
us
attend
to
each
of
these
ever‐resurrecting
vampires.
 
 Fallacy
1:

 “Markets
cannot
fail.
Unemployment
is
caused
by
resource
owners
being
unwilling
to
 accept
the
market
clearing
price.
It
is
voluntary
in
the
sense
of
being
the
result
of
our
 own
free
choices.
Governments
spending
money
they
have
printed
do
not
supply
 anything
in
return
for
what
they
buy.
Governments
that
instead
borrow
money
repay
 by
printing
money
or
taking
money
from
taxpayers.
Rational
buyers
won’t
give
up
 something
for
nothing.”


 
 Rebuttal:
 
 In
a
deep
slump,
a
wide
and
complicated
network
of
financial
connections
has
been
 disrupted
or
destroyed.
Money
flows
required
for
debt
repayments
and
purchases
of
inputs
 and
outputs
contract.
Isolated
individuals
cannot
repair
a
network
of
coordination
across
 space
and
time.
They
can
only
reconfigure
the
system
slowly,
one
pair
of
connections
at
a
 time.
By
contrast,
a
government
can
take
a
system‐wide
viewpoint
and
inject
funds
widely
to
 restore
viable
connections
simultaneously
across
the
economy.
Governments
can
supply
 coordination
and
clarity.
Printing
and
distributing
money
is
supplying
a
valuable
service.
 
 Cutting
your
price
in
terms
of
money
does
not
re‐activate
trade.
Choosing
to
offer
your
 labour
at
too
high
a
wage
or
choosing
to
supply
output
at
too
high
a
price
are
not
what
 19

But see Barro (1996) for his earnest attempt to deflect O’Driscoll (1977). Barro’s ignorance of Keynesian texts (and certainly his lack of intuitive understanding of them) is rather clearer. He claims that Keynes stressed wage-andprice inflexibility as crucial to obtaining his results. But see Keynes (1936, ch. 2, ch. 19). Alas, Barro writes textbooks.


frustrates
market
exchange
during
a
macroeconomic
slump.
New
classical
economists
simply
 do
not
grasp
how
unemployment
can
be
involuntary.
Many
classical
economists
cannot
 grasp
that
the
“real
balance
effect”20
upon
which
some
misapplications
of
Say’s
Law
 ultimately
depend,
has
no
role
in
a
real‐world
monetary
economy.

 
 Spending
raises
output

 
 All
economists
know
that
in
reality
an
increase
in
the
money
supply
raises
output,
at
least
 over
the
short
period.
The
quantity
theory
is
a
long‐term
theory.
In
the
short
term,
 quantities
respond
and
the
economy
reflates.
During
a
typical
market
slump
(one
caused
by
 a
sudden
decline
in
private‐sector
spending),
upward
pressure
on
prices
is
weak
to
non‐ existent.

 
 Demand
is
someone
with
money
spending
it.
Even
those
who
claim
to
uphold
Say’s
Law
 know
that
higher
demand
elicits
an
increase
in
the
quantity
supplied.
Elementary
 microeconomics
shows
this:
D
right
leads
to
increase
in
p
and
q.
In
the
case
of
an
increase
in
 total
spending,
demand
curves
for
each
normal
good
would
shift
to
the
right.
 (For
simplicity
keep
the
nominal
price
of
inputs
and
technology
constant
so
that
the
MC
line
 is
unchanged
throughout.)
 
 Suppose
there
is
an
increase
in
demand
caused
by
a
fiscal
injection
calculated
to
return
total
 demand
to
normal.
This
means
that
the
positions
of
the
demand
curve
of
each
good
on
 average
returns
to
normal21.

 
 In
the
case
of
a
broadly
based
stimulus,
spending
is
widely
spread
across
the
economy.

A
 firm
neither
knows
nor
cares
where
the
money
(its
extra
revenue)
came
from.
It
may
have
 come
from
overdrafts
or
by
dishoarding.
It
may
have
been
newly
printed
and
dropped
by
a
 helicopter,
or
as
payment
to
workers
and
firms
to
build
a
road.
It
could
be
a
tax
rebate
or
a
 gift
to
households
from
the
government.
It
does
not
matter
much
what
the
source
of
 demand
is.
The
factors
of
production
were
happy
to
produce
this
output
before
in
normal
 times
and
at
the
then
prevailing
normal
nominal
price.
The
demand
curve
returns
to
normal,
 and
p
and
q
of
each
typical
firm
returns
to
normal.
And
the
factors
of
production
will
find
 that
their
real
remuneration
will
return
to
normal.

 
 For
recovery,
the
supply
curve
does
not
need
to
shift
to
the
right
for
the
fiscal
stimulus
to
 succeed.
Improving
incentives
by
cutting
tax
rates,
freeing
up
labour
markets,
providing
 more
infrastructure
and
so
on
are
simply
not
required
for
output
to
rise
towards
a
higher
 sustainable
level.

 
 Even
unproductive
consumption
spending
raises
short‐term
income
and
promotes
 restoration
of
normal
or
trend
GDP.
Simply
dropping
money
from
a
helicopter
may
have
a
 This is the idea, long ago discredited, that deflation will raise the real purchasing power of money. As prices and wages approach zero, purchasing power approaches infinity. Of course, as the price level collapses, so does the economy, politics and social structures in general. Mathematical “economists” are routinely blind to this. 21 It is not possible for centralised expenditure to replicate an outcome for each demand curve exactly the same as the outcome resulting from a restoration of confidence by the private sector. Austrians bemoan the ruinous distortions that are claimed to result, but “near enough is good enough” in an emergency for us Keynesians. An urgent life-saving operation may leave an unsightly scar. That’s a pity, but the patient ought to be grateful considering the alternative. 20


similar
effect,
but
it
helps
if
the
money
drops
are
targeted
in
a
way
that
those
who
pick
the
 money
up
are
likely
soon
to
spend
it.
Greater
spending
raises
output
regardless
of
the
type
 of
spending.

This
is
equivalent
to
Friedman’s
(1969,
p.4)
famous
helicopter
example,
 if
it
is
newly
created
rather
than
borrowed
money.

http://www.ronpaulforums.com/showthread.php?p=1780466

Friedman
regarded
any
increase
in
the
money
supply
as
essentially
monetary
policy,
even
if
 it
was
delivered
by
fiscal
means,
such
as
a
tax
cut,
government
spending
or
a
cash
payment.
 Friedman
clearly
was
a
demand‐side
economist;
it’s
just
that
he
argued
that
governments
in
 practice
were
unable
to
fine‐tune
total
spending
and
should
not
pretend
that
they
could.

 This
means
that
other
economists,
who
reject
demand‐side
economics
root
and
branch,
do
 not
always
agree
with
Friedman.
 
 In
Friedman
it
does
not
matter
much
how
the
new
money
entered
the
economy.
In
 Keynesian
economics,
it
does
matter
whether
the
injection
occurs
in
the
expenditure
stream
 (fiscal
policy
by
their
definition)
or
in
the
financial
sector
(monetary
policy).
Keynesians
often
 regard
easier
monetary
policy
via
open
market
operations
(where
the
central
bank
buys
 bonds)
as
less
reliable
in
slumps.
Funds
may
sit
in
financial
portfolios
and
not
reach
the
 expenditure
stream
in
a
predictable
or
timely
manner.
Consumers
spend
most
of
a
tax
cut
or


an
increase
in
transfer
payments,
and
all
government
spending
by
definition
is
injected
into
 the
circular
flow
of
income.
 
 Friedman
and
the
Keynesians
agree
that
it
does
not
matter
at
first
that
at
the
point
of
initial
 demand
stimulus
the
government
supplied
nothing
more
than
money22.
Demand
drives
 output
over
the
short
term.
There
is
the
same
response
if
the
recovery
had
instead
resulted
 from
a
restoration
of
willingness
to
spend
by
the
private
sector
through
dishoarding
(or
by
 bank
overdraft).

 
 Suppose
that
the
government
has
the
will
and
expertise
to
follow
Keynesian
teaching
during
 the
entire
business
cycle.
When
the
confidence
of
the
private‐sector
recovers
sooner
or
later
 during
a
robust
recovery
phase,
the
government
extracts
as
much
as
is
required
of
the
new
 money
it
created
or
injected
in
its
stimulus
package
(road
building
perhaps).

 
 All
that
is
then
left
behind
is
a
new
road,
and
better
a
road
that
currently
leads
nowhere
 than
no
road
at
all.
And
it
will
probably
lead
somewhere
one
day.
There
is
no
more
of
a
 “distortion”
in
allocation
than
if
a
natural
event
made
transport
easier
than
before.
A
road
 that
is
built,
or
a
river
that
is
navigable,
is
there
to
be
used.
A
road
that
is
built
is
largely
a
 sunk
cost.
There
is
no
opportunity
cost
if
all
the
cost
is
sunk.
If
the
choice
is
between
a
road
 to
nowhere
and
no
output
at
all,
the
former
involves
greater
aggregate
economic
wealth.
If
 resources
later
are
attracted
to
the
river,
there
is
no
market
“distortion”.
If
resources
are
 attracted
to
a
road,
likewise
there
is
no
distortion
in
allocation.
 
 
 Fallacy
2:

 “Government
spending
cannot
raise
employment
because
government 
borrowing
reduces
private
spending.”
 (e.g.,
John
Cochrane,
University
of
Chicago)
 
 Partial
Rebuttal:
 
 
This
is
simply
the
notorious
British
“Treasury
view”
of
the
1920s
and
1930s.
The
claim
is
that
 public
spending
fully
crowds
out
private
spending,
or
the
multiplier
is
zero.
The
rejoinder
 that
seemed
obvious
at
the
time
is
that
idle
money
(or
unused
lines
of
bank
and
trade
credit)
 exists
in
a
general
business
slump
because
nobody
in
the
private
sector
is
willing
to
borrow
it
 to
buy
new
investment
goods23.
The
seemingly
simple
solution
is
for
the
government
to
 borrow
this
idle
money
(or
even
print
new
money)
and
place
orders
for
capital
 infrastructure.
This
breaks
the
vicious
cycle
that
the
market
economy
had
stumbled
into.

Old-style Keynesians tended not to care much whether this money was newly printed or borrowed from the holdings (hoards) of wealth holders. 23 There is a long, largely forgotten, theoretical debate about why those with excess cash will not lend it at a rate of interest low enough for the borrower to accept. In the real world, we know that Keynes was right. A loss of spending confidence by households (a decline in consumption) does not, over any reasonably short time frame, raise the supply of saving and sufficiently reduce the rate of interest on loans for investment projects by firms. If anything, a sudden increase in saving is associated with business pessimism and a decline in investment. The possible long-term connection between saving by households and investing by firms is a separate issue, and it is not directly relevant to short-term demand management (according to Keynesians). 22


People
don’t
seem
to
realise
that
in
the
Treasury
View
even
a
contractionary
policy
would
 not
contract.
When
it
comes
the
time
to
raise
taxes
to
repay
the
fiscal
debt,
nothing
 unpleasant
happens.

 
 Tax
cuts

 During
February
2009,
we
all
viewed
a
political
pantomime
when
discussions
shifted
to
 discussions
about
the
size
and
mix
of
the
urgently
proposed
stimulus
package.
The
“debate”
 in
February
frequently
converged
to
the
proposition
that
productive
infrastructure
would
be
 ideal
stimulus.
Next
best
would
be
tax
cuts.
The
Federal
government
does
not
have
projects
 ready
to
go,
so
the
lead
times
(part
of
the
inside
lag,
as
macroeconomists
say)
are
 impracticably
long.
(See
a
later
section
for
an
exploration
of
this
point.)

 
 Attention
now
turns
to
whether
lump‐sum
transfer
payments
to
households
(reverse‐flow
 taxes)
would
be
more
effective
in
imparting
fast
and
large
fiscal
thrust
than
cuts
in
the
rate
 of
taxation
on
household
and
corporate
income,
the
third
way
tax
cuts
could
provide
 stimulus.

The
Coalition
appeared
to
argue
that
the
fiscal
stimulus
should
have
been
about
half
the
size
 and
delivered
by
cuts
in
tax
rates
rather
than
by
cash
payments.
Parliamentary
debate
and
 concurrent
commentary
related
to
the
following
question:

Which provides greater fiscal stimulus? 1. A cash payment of $950 this year. (Labor) 2. An unspecified ongoing cut in the marginal tax rate, but one unlikely to result in a tax cut of about $500 in any one year so that this year’s deficit increase won’t be as large. (Coalition)

This
is
a
rather
vague
question,
but
people
confidently
answered
it.
How
on
earth
does
one
 compare
a
single
once‐off
cash
payment
with
an
ongoing
cut
in
marginal
tax
rates?
 Attention
came
to
centre
on
the
difference
between
temporary
and
more
permanent
 stimulus.
John
Taylor
and
Milton
Friedman
were
enlisted
by
the
Opposition
in
support
of
the
 claim
that
cutting
tax
rates
was
more
“permanent”
than
a
“once‐off”
windfall.
Thus
tax
cuts
 would
yield
a
greater
stimulus,
according
to
the
permanent
income
hypothesis.

 
 Friedman
argued
that
fiscal
policy
was
uselessly
weak
as
a
tool
of
counter‐cyclical
demand
 management.
A
tax
cut
in
a
slump
will
be
removed
later
when
the
economy
fully
recovers24.
 The
restoration
of
normal
capacity
utilisation
would
normally
take
a
year
or
two,
or
more.
 Such
tax
cuts
are
temporary
in
Friedman’s
system.
At
best
we
are
arguing
about
whether
a
 temporary
cut
is
much
stronger
than
a
very
temporary
(once‐off)
cut.

 
 If
the
Coalition
advocated
cuts
that
would
only
last
for
a
year
or
two,
Friedman
would
have
 rejected
their
proposal
–
and
so
would
John
Taylor.

24

I don’t recall Friedman going further and saying that it was important that it would be reversed in the next boom. Friedman’s agents are not as super-rational and forward-looking as in New Classicism.


According
to
John
Taylor
in
an
interview
with
Fran
Kelly
on
RN,
one
should
reduce
the
tax
 rates
for
“a
while”.
Perhaps
this
time
span
is
measured
with
…
a
piece
of
string.
In
the
Wall
 Street
Journal,
Taylor
(2008)
advocates
enacting
tax
cuts
that
last
for
more
than
just
a
year
 or
two.
This
is
consistent
with
the
medium
to
long‐term
focus
he
places
on
fiscal
policy
in
his
 textbook.
This
strategy
only
makes
sense
if
tax
rates
were
too
high
in
the
trend
sense
to
 begin
with.
It’s
not
obvious
that
it’s
good
short‐term
management
to
commit
credibly
to
 hold
tax
rates
low
for
too
long
so
that
people
will
regard
them
as
“permanent”
and
spend
 them.
Perhaps
Taylor
believes
that
tax
rates
drift
up
too
high
and
that
recessions
are
 politically
advantageous
times
to
cut
them
back
to
where
they
should
be.
Alternatively,
 perhaps
the
financial
crisis
has
been
so
destructive
that
incentives
to
produce
need
to
be
 increased
for
several
years
while
potential
supply
heals
and
the
effects
of
the
negative
 shocks
to
financial
technology
have
faded.


 
 A
better
defined
question
is
this:
 Which provides greater fiscal stimulus? 1. A quick once-off cash payment of $950 this year 2. A once-off cut in the marginal rate resulting in a taxcut of $950 spread over the year Answer: The spending stimuli are the same over the entire year. If speed of injection matters, option 1 hits the expenditure stream quicker, and this would probably trump the small additional supply-side stimulus offered by 2.

To
sensibly
answer
questions
like
these,
you
need
to
frame
the
options
properly.

 
 1. You
must
have
definite
alternatives
regarding
both
size
and
duration.
 2. You
must
compare
a
series
of
single
payments
with
an
extended
tax‐cut
of
the
same
 size
 
 Which provides greater fiscal stimulus? 1. Cash payments of $X in a year repeated for as long as required 2. An equivalent cut of $X in a year via a cut in the marginal rate that applies for as long as required Answer: About the same? Option 1 is more flexible in timing and delivery. But option 2 has the added supply-side effect. 
 
 Lump‐sum
rebates
were
argued
by
the
government
to
be
quicker
means
to
put
cash
into
 people’s
hands
and
better
able
to
be
targeted
to
those
who
would
spend
it
quickly.
 
 First,
there
is
speed
of
delivery
and
impact.
A
quick
burst
of
ammunition
may
obviate
the
 need
to
use
more
up
later,
and
those
concerned
about
fiscal
deficits
quickly
worry
that
the


ammunition
is
running
out.
But
we
may
have
confused
haste
with
speed,
if
the
stimulus
is
 crudely
delivered
and
poorly
targeted.
Those
most
in
need
of
support
should
already
have
 been
identified
and
protocols
in
place
for
the
delivery
of
these
funds.
We
should
be
 permanently
prepared
to
deal
with
sudden
emergencies.

 
 Second,
there
are
fewer
people
today
who
are
cash
constrained
and
desperate
to
buy
 necessities.
One
must
concede
that
the
Australian
cash‐payment
packages
have
been
poorly
 targeted.
For
example,
I
shall
receive
the
second
payment
in
April
(as
a
result
of
the
February
 decision),
and
my
marginal
propensity
to
consume
is
zero.
But
(relatively)
affluent
academic
 economists
should
not
extrapolate
from
their
own
experience
and
dismiss
the
payout
as
 mere
pocket
money
(c.f.
Makin
2009b).
 
 It
is
commonly
estimated
that
up
to
80%
of
the
government's
first
(December
2008)
stimulus
 package
in
of
$10.4
billion
had
been
saved
and
not
spent,
which
makes
the
fiscal
transfer
 payment
multiplier
small.
If
the
funds
were
used
to
repay
credit
card
debt
and
rebuild
 buffers
(repair
balance
sheets),
then
the
resilience
of
future
spending
is
enhanced.
People
 may
be
saving
on
precautionary
grounds,
so
that
they
can
spend
if
conditions
worsen.
If
the
 slump
turns
out
to
be
lengthy,
then
these
funds
will
still
handily
dribble
from
saving
into
the
 expenditure
stream.
 
 One
idea
to
get
more
bangs
for
the
fiscal
buck
is
a
debit
card
that
could
only
be
used
in
retail
 outlets
over
a
brief
time
span
to
supposedly
ensure
100%
of
government
stimulus
dollars
are
 spent
rather
than
saved.25
Similar
is
the
US
proposal,
Barnett
(2009)
to
give
children
 vouchers
to
buy
toys
and
games.
And
Makin
(2009b)
makes
the
same
point
about
payment’s
 to
fund
children’s
consumption,
though
with
heavy
irony.

 
 At
this
point
(and
probably
much
earlier),
you
would
be
thinking
that
there
must
be
better
 ways
to
inject
stimulus.
Had
we
been
better
prepared,
there
certainly
would
be.
I
know
of
 nobody
(retailers
aside)
who
would
not
prefer
to
target
fiscal
stimulus
to
infrastructure.
But
 time
may
be
of
the
essence.

 
 
 Government
spending
 
 Government
spending
(G)
is
claimed
to
have
some
advantages
over
taxes
in
affecting
total
 spending.
But
there
are
drawbacks
too.
An
obvious
point
is
that
altering
G
has
long
lead
 times
and
this
may
make
G
unsuitable
as
a
countercyclical
instrument.
Few
projects
are
soon
 “shovel‐ready”.
The
first
subsection
will
look
at
how
the
implementation
lag,
part
of
the
so‐ called
inside
lag26,
may
be
reduced.

 
 Reducing
the
inside
lag
 
 State
governments
already
have
infrastructure
projects
in
the
pipeline.
Why
not
accelerate
 these
and
provide
federal
funds?
The
standard
Keynesian
policy
is
to
spend
on
infrastructure
 during
slumps,
which
is
precisely
when
this
sector
is
disproportionately
affected.
This
policy
 25

AAP (2009) The inside lag includes the time taken to recognise the problem, decide what to do and then actually do it. The outside lag refers to how long it takes for these actions to have the bulk of their multiplier impact. 26


puts
idle
skilled
labour
to
good
use,
saves
households
from
unemployment
and
protects
the
 private‐sector’s
balance
sheet.
The
State
government
stands
as
a
body
shield
between
 households
and
the
global
financial
crisis.

 
 By
contrast
the
State
Opposition
prior
to
the
recent
election
(it
lost)
had
promised
to
 balance
the
budget
by
the
end
of
its
first
term
(even
though
the
global
slump
is
likely
to
 persist
for
the
next
few
years).
This
is
the
fiscal
equivalent
of
the
army
opening
fire
on
its
 own
citizens.
It
took
Hayek
decades
to
recover
his
credibility
and
prestige
after
being
almost
 alone
among
leading
economists
of
advocating
balanced
budgets
and
rejecting
easy
 monetary
policy
in
the
1930s.
He
is
favourably
remembered
today
mostly
for
other
 contributions.

 
 The
States’
emergency
borrowing
required
to
sustain
or
increase
infrastructure
spending
 could
be
done
by
or
backed
by
the
Commonwealth,
which
would
help
protect
the
credit
 ratings
of
the
States27.
Again
we
have
been
caught
with
our
trousers
down28,
and
despite
 many
months
to
prepare
and
debate
contingency
plans,
the
government
and
the
Treasury
 have
done
little
to
prepare
for
direct
and
predictable
impacts
on
the
fiscal
positions
of
the
 States.
There
may
be
rational
concerns
about
the
efficiency
with
which
the
States
invest
in
 infrastructure,
but
is
the
problem
that
Federal
politicians
want
the
kudos
and
are
unwilling
 to
fund
State
projects?
 
 Idle
thoughts

 
 If
the
dispute
is
to
be
resolved
about
the
potential
value
of
counter‐cyclical
demand
 management
by
fiscal
policy,
then
isolating
the
source,
if
there
is
just
one,
of
the
 disagreement
would
be
helpful.
If
we
have
learned
anything
from
the
debates
so
far,
there
is
 a
consistent
source
of
disagreement
between
classical
economics
and
Keynesian
economics.

 
 Classical
theory
emphasises
efficient
resource
allocation
and
a
flexible
micro‐structure.
 According
to
the
Keynesian
view,
this
emphasis
is
fine
if
the
economy
is
operating
at
target
 capacity
(full
employment,
for
simplicity).
But
if
resources
and
money
initially
are
idle,
then
 completely
different
dynamics
come
into
operation
and
a
completely
different
analytical
 framework
is
needed.
Stories
that
are
valid
at
full
employment
become
dangerously
wrong
 outside
this
domain.

 
 We
have
already
explored
the
issue
of
idle
resources,
what
about
the
issue
of
idle
money?
 This
draws
us
to
consider
rival
views
about
how
the
financial
sector
works
and
the
 importance
of
the
healthy
operation
of
the
financial
sector
to
the
effective
operation
of
the
 real
(goods
and
services)
sector.
The
global
financial
crisis
has
forced
us
to
revisit
debates
of
 the
1930s
about
saving,
financial
wealth
and
investment
in
real
production
capacity.

 
 The
Austrian
View
 
 The
sharpest
and
most
potentially
instructive
contrasts
with
Keynesian
reasoning
stems
 from
the
Austrian
school
of
classical
economics.
Financial
markets
work
well
if
governments
 See AFR, Monday March 2, 2009, p.1. I can only treat with disdain the observation that this condition is ideal when urgent stimulus is needed. Metaphors break down. 27

28


leave
them
alone.
Tinkering
with
the
money
supply
and
interest
rates
distort
the
size
and
 composition
of
investment
and
exacerbate
cycles
instead
of
reducing
them
as
intended.

 
 The
financial
sector
leads
the
way.
When
it
is
allowed
to
work
properly,
the
real
sector
then
 produces
the
right
size
and
mix
of
output.
Saved
funds
return
to
the
real
economy
as
 productive
investment
in
due
course
after
an
efficient
linking
and
networking
of
financial
 flows
through
space
and
time.
Keynesians
are
wrong
to
regard
these
funds
as
“idle”
and
ripe
 for
borrowing.
Whether
circulating
around
the
financial
system
or
sitting
in
a
short‐term
 savings
vehicle,
these
funds
are
busily
linking
present
saving
to
future
consumption.
Just
as
 investment
is
roundabout,
so
is
finance.

 
 
 The
Keynesian
view
 
 The
Keynesians
see
the
economy
in
terms
of
aggregates.
A
rising
tide
raises
all
boats.
Of
 course,
a
rising
tide
does
not
raise
the
seaworthiness
of
any
of
the
boats.
Neither
does
it
 raise
the
skills
of
any
of
their
crew,
but
these
faults
at
the
micro‐level
are
not
the
central
 concern
of
Keynesians.
The
Keynesians
tend
to
regard
simple
hydraulic
metaphors
as
 representing
simple
attributes
worthy
of
modelling.
Economies
as
a
whole
can
be
pumped
 up
and
they
can
be
contracted.

 
 The
Keynesian
approach
to
financial
markets
is
also
macro:
a
rising
financial
tide
raises
all
 assets.
The
fine
microstructure
of
financial
markets
is
no
more
crucial
than
the
fine
 microstructure
of
the
real
economy.
Indeed,
financial
markets
are
often
more
speculative
 and
unruly
than
product
markets
and
price
outcomes
are
less
likely
to
be
grounded
in
 objectively
verifiable
conditions
or
in
stable
conventions.
The
value
of
both
real
assets
(gold,
 art,
antiques)
as
well
as
the
value
of
financial
assets
(bonds,
derivatives,
shares)
can
vary
 with
shifts
in
market
sentiment.
The
stock
of
savings
can
be
regarded
a
pool,
though
it
need
 not
be
flat
and
quiescent.
During
a
slump,
funds
may
be
siphoned
by
government
 borrowings
and
returned
to
the
circular
flow
of
income.
Prosperity
increases
the
pool
of
 savings:
as
income
rises,
replenishing
funds
flow
back
into
the
pool
of
saving.

 
 At
very
low
interest
rates
it
may
be
that
the
only
buyer
of
long
securities
is
the
government,
 and
they
are
paying
high
prices
by
historical
standards.
Instead
of
spending
or
on‐lending
 these
funds,
wealth
owners
speculate
that
interest
rates
can
only
go
up.
They
will
wait
 accordingly
for
bond
prices
to
fall
and
re‐purchase
the
bonds
they
have
just
sold
to
the
 central
bank.
This
is
the
“liquidity
trap.”
Open
market
operations
cease
to
be
effective.
But
 this
is
the
very
case
where
bond
sales
to
fund
fiscal
stimulus
should
be
easier.
 
 The
early
Keynesian
vision
was
of
wealthy,
do‐nothing,
coupon‐clipping
rentiers
being
 rewarded
merely
for
“waiting”.
Siphoning
funds
from
them
can
do
no
harm
to
production;
 indeed,
their
gradual
and
automatic
“euthanasia”
in
a
maturing
economy
is
something
to
 look
forward
to.

 
 Keynesians
often
speak
of
idle
money
as
the
counterpart
of
idle
resources.
They
argue
that
 fiscal
policy
can
impart
stimulus
if
monetary
policy
cannot.
Idle
savings
can
be
borrowed
and
 re‐injected
into
the
circular
flow.
If
funding
extra
government
outlays
by
printing
new
money
 is
unacceptable,
the
necessary
funds
can
be
borrowed.


Anti‐Keynesians
retort
that
funds
in
reality
are
seldom
idle
or
unproductive.
While
brief
 periods
of
hoarding
are
possible,
saved
funds
generally
are
put
to
work
to
earn
a
return,
and
 real
returns
can
be
sustained
only
by
increases
in
real
productivity.
If
someone
puts
money
 in
the
bank
to
save
up
for
a
holiday,
these
funds
are
used
by
someone
else
in
the
meantime.
 The
complex
tendrils
of
asset
and
finance
markets
are
too
opaque
and
delicately
structured
 to
allow
heavy
macro‐interventions,
especially
in
the
form
of
lorry
loads
of
broadly
 homogeneous
government
paper
being
dumped
in
one
part
of
the
system.
 
 The
Keynesian
use
of
the
term,
“idle”,
has
probably
misled
many
people,
including
some
 Keynesians.
Money
held
as
wealth
in
the
financial
sector
may
be
whizzing
around
from
one
 financial
market
to
the
next.
Money
can
be
“hot”
and
energetic
or
it
can
instead
sit
in
cold
 storage
in
a
term
deposit.
The
asset
velocity
of
money
may
be
extremely
high,
but
its
income
 velocity
may
be
low.
Funds
churned
furiously
do
not
lead
to
the
generation
of
currently
 produced
goods
and
services.
Asset
prices
(house
prices,
share
prices)
rise,
but
the
 production
of
new
houses
and
new
factories
lags,
or
never
eventuates.
Asset
bubbles
lack
 real
substance:
there
is
a
serious
disconnect
between
financial
markets
and
the
real
 economy.
Keynesians
believe
that
this
circuit
of
funds
from
savers
to
investors
is
slow,
weak
 and
unreliable.
If
you
have
studied
first‐year
economics,
this
is
why
investment
is
 autonomous
(and
not
connected
to
saving),
at
least
in
the
short
run.
Asset
markets
are
not
 efficient
in
most
renditions
of
Keynes29.

 
 
 One
has
to
admit
that
Keynesians
have
unwisely
dismissed
the
possible
intricacies
of
 financial
network.
The
Keynesian
assumption
that
the
financial
sector
can
adapt
rapidly
to
 digest
large
volumes
of
government
bonds
should
have
been
subjected
to
more
critical
 scrutiny.
Funds
may
not
simply
be
there
to
be
easily
siphoned
off.
What
Keynesians
regard
 as
mere
liposuction
of
surplus
fat,
Austrians
regard
as
the
excision
of
crucial
healthy
tissue.

 
 
 Meeting
in
the
middle?
 
 Let
me
put
words
into
the
mouths
of
Keynesians
in
the
hope
of
opening
dialogue
with
the
 Austrian
school.
Markets
have
missed
the
opportunity
of
using
resources
productively
while
 supposedly
generating
complex
optimal
solutions
to
problems
of
coordination
of
saving
and
 investment
through
time.
A
flow
of
bridging
finance
to
preserve
full
employment
during
the
 transition
has
failed
to
emerge
through
market
forces30.
By
borrowing
money
and
returning
 it
to
the
circular
flow
of
income
by
expansionary
fiscal
policy,
needless
unemployment
is
 avoided.

 
 A
Keynesian
may
be
justified
in
arguing
that
funds
once
supporting
bubbles
are
better
 diverted
to
fund
government
infrastructure.
In
the
Keynesian
world
view,
funds
circulating
in
 “New” Keynesians defend rational expectations and the efficiency of asset markets. In this important respect, they scarcely deserve to be called Keynesians at all. 30 Relying on input and output prices to free-fall would be the Austrian “solution”, but Keynesians would regard this as price overshooting and the spreading and amplification of the market failure as the resulting deflation is likely to generate a perverse market spiral and possible implosion. You are free to disagree, but do acknowledge that the argument is there and deserves to be addressed and not dismissed out of hand. You may regard reasoning or the assumptions that underpin it as fanciful, but do appreciate its internal coherence. 29


the
financial
sector
are
not
in
an
elaborate
process
of
an
upcoming
and
triumphant
return
to
 the
circular
flow
of
income.
Savers
have
put
funds
in
liquid
form
because
they
are
uncertain.
 They
do
knot
know
what
they
want
to
buy
or
when
they
want
it.
Entrepreneurship
is
about
 animal
spirits,
not
the
accurate
semi‐clairvoyant
guessing
of
what
consumers
in
future
will
 want
to
buy.
If
anything,
saving
sends
a
false
signal
to
investors
and
firms.
Higher
saving
 signals
to
sellers
that
purchasers
do
not
want
the
product.
It
is
unlikely
that
any
sensible
firm
 would
interpret
low
consumption
today
as
expressing
the
desire
for
more
consumption
 tomorrow31.
Quite
the
contrary
would
likely
be
the
case.
Indeed,
if
we
are
referring
to
short‐ term
fluctuations,
sudden
changes
in
consumer
sentiment
will
be
associated,
if
anything,
 with
a
decline
in
investment.
Even
classical
economists
must
know
this
basic
fact.32
The
 effect
on
trend
investment
of
a
gradual
and
sustained
increase
in
the
rate
of
saving
is
a
 different
issue.

 
 Both
the
Austrian
and
the
Keynesian
positions
are
perfectly
intelligible
and
each
may
be
 valid
in
a
particular
time
or
place.
These
judgements
are
central
to
the
art
of
economics.
 Keynes’s
point
was
that
the
stock
of
saving
is
very
large,
and
some
of
the
money
now
 churned
in
the
financial
sector
can
be
borrowed
and
spent
on
G
without
significantly
 reducing
the
ability
of
private
investors
to
obtain
funds
for
real
investment.
You
can
agree
or
 disagree,
but
the
point
is
whether
you
understand
what
economists
are
disagreeing
about.

 
 Fiscal
Policy
Rules,
OK?
 
 Suppose
the
preceding
lengthy
discussion
lends
weight
to
the
proposition
that,
in
principle,
 fiscal
policy
could
work.
The
next
question
is
how
to
make
it
work
better
in
practice.
What
 follows
is
an
outline
of
fiscal
reform33

.

 
 We
could
have
a
set
of
fiscal
policy
rules
appropriate
for
a)
financial
disruptions,
b)
short‐ term
demand
management
and
c)
long‐term
stability.
These
rules
would
be
pre‐announced
 and
be
implemented
independently
of
politicians.
Politicians
would
need
to
approve
of
 these
rules
or
the
process
by
which
these
rules
are
decided.

 
 a)

 In
an
asset
boom
of
10%,
raise
capital
gains
taxes
by
y%
as
a
pre‐emptive
strike
against
 bubbles.
 In
a
crisis,
move
spending
projects
X,
Y
and
Z
forwards.

 In
a
crisis,
make
emergency
payments
prioritising
persons
in
the
following
categories…
 
 b)

 In
a
boom
(slump)
of
1%,
raise
(cut)
direct
taxes
by
x%.
 In
a
boom
(slump)
of
2%,
raise
(cut)
the
GST
by
x%
for
6
months
only34
 This view stems from the early pages of chapter 16 of The General Theory, and forms part of Axel Leijonhufvud’s interpretation of Keynes (Appendix 1). 32 They may interpret it differently though: wise investors overlook short-term noise. If thrift turns out to be sustained, there will be a lag before an excess supply for consumption results in the excess demand for investment becoming realised in the form of extra output of investment goods. This argument concerning logistic lags in structural readjustment features surprisingly little in debates over the coordination of saving and investment. 33 I broadly approve of Henry Ergas’ call for a temporary cut in the GST, an indirect tax. But I would bind GST changes to a rule. See and Taylor (2005, p. 247; 2009, p. 265). However, I do not speak for Taylor at all. An alternative would be to raise the GST threshold. 31


In
a
slump
(boom),
move
projects
A
and
Z
forwards
(back).
 
 c)

 Over
the
longer
term,
aim
for
a
balanced
budget
(on
average
the
structural
balance
should
 be
zero)
or
some
small
deficit
if
long‐term
infrastructure
is
debt‐funded.
 
 
 In
this
way,
fiscal
responses
in
response
to
actual
and
potential
crises
become
assertive,
 agile
and
alert.
Crisis
management
should
be
triple
A.
These
rules
are
quite
predictable
in
 their
mode
of
implementation,
but
flexibility
is
preserved.
Additionally,
short‐term
 stabilisation
is
enhanced
as
timely
interventions
in
the
face
of
crises
and
bubbles
would
 reduce
the
amplitude
of
fluctuations,
and
longer‐term
fiscal
settings
are
not
compromised.

 
 During
routine
fluctuations,
the
TTT
(temporary,
targeted,
timely)
principles
would
apply.
 The
rationale
of
targeting
expenditures
and
tax
cuts,
“more
bangs
for
the
buck”,
is
intended
 to
provide
a
quick
injection,
especially
so
that
those
with
little
can
at
least
keep
most
of
 what
the
have.

Even
if
not
large,
an
early
stimulus
may
pre‐empt
a
social
hardship.
 Targeting
would
also
pertain
to
industries
and
regions
selected
either
for
alleviation
of
 distress,
availability
of
idle
resources
or
for
longer‐term
development.
 
 Over
the
longer
term
PPP
(permanent,
pervasive,
predictable)
apply.
Overall,
the
strategy
is
 “ATP”:
the
As
apply
if
urgent
action
is
needed,
the
Ts
typify
short‐term
management,
and
 the
Ps
provide
long‐term
protocols.
The
point
is
to
get
G*
and
t*,
the
trend
values
of
G
and
 the
trend
marginal
tax
rate
(scale),
correct
in
the
light
of
the
provision
of
public
goods
and
 the
achievement
of
other
long‐term
social
goals.
Over
the
short
term,
automatic
stabilisation
 can
be
used
as
well
as
an
active
rule
to
manipulate
structural
deficits.
If
monetary
policy
is
 used
in
tandem,
these
structural
changes
are
likely
to
be
relatively
small.

 
 Even
the
champion
of
activist
monetary
policy,
John
Taylor,
sees
scope
for
fiscal
easing
now.
 Taylor’s
fiscal
orientation
is
conservative.
Rely
on
automatic
stabilisation
to
limit
the
 downturn
and
cut
tax
rates
to
improve
the
longer‐term
recovery
of
trend
growth
as
 aggregate
supply
reconfigures.
So
he
rejects
the
principles
underpinning
recent
short‐term
 stabilisation
packages,
TTT
(temporary,
targeted,
timely),
in
favour
of
a
longer‐term
 approach
based
on
PPP
(permanent,
pervasive,
predictable).

 
 Remarkably,
conservative
economists
have
advocated
policies
that
would
take
several
years
 to
have
an
effect.
This
may
be
based
on
their
suspicion
of
the
efficacy
of
short‐term
“sugar‐ hit”
outlays
based
on
cash
handouts
and
ad
hoc
expenditures.
Cuts
in
marginal
tax
rates
are
 popular
–
e.g.,
Kates35,
Makin.
The
IMF
has
even
suggested
increasing
the
retirement
age,
 presumably
to
make
it
easier
for
governments
later
to
collect
enough
taxes
to
unwind
their
 fiscal
deficits;
see
Uren
(2009).
These
policies
don’t
make
much
sense
in
the
current
context,
 except
so
far
as
now
is
as
good
a
time
as
any
to
get
long‐term
settings
right.
By
contrast,
in
 the
ATP
approach,
PPP
would
be
the
long‐term
criteria,
and
TTT
would
inform
short‐term
 stabilisation.
 Payments to the States could be averaged over the cycle, or, better, extra revenue raised in booms would be passed to the States in slumps. 35 Even Kates is friendly to tax cuts (supply-side fiscal action), but he presumably would still strive to balance the budget. 34


The
ATP
approach
in
summary:
 
 Short‐term
crisis
responses
 Short‐term
stabilisation
 Longer‐term
strategy

AAA
 TTT
 PPP

Assertive,
agile
and
alert.
 Temporary,
targeted,
timely
 Permanent,
pervasive,
 predictable

Brad
DeLong
(2006)
argued
that
it
may
be
time
for
a
fiscal
stabilisation
board
made
up
of
 “thoughtful,
public
spirited
technocrats”
like
those
on
the
Board
of
the
Fed.
He
trusted
that
 they
would
expand
deficits
only
for
non‐political
reasons.
He
provided
no
details36.

 
 
 Conclusions
 
 This
paper
strives
to
make
clear
what
Keynesians
and
classicists
are
assuming,
in
many
cases
 tacitly.
In
principle,
there
is
a
legitimate
domain
for
each
body
of
thought.

Truth
cannot
 contradict
truth
(as
JP2
said
in
1996).
The
choice
may
appear
bleak.
Keynesians
are
 highhanded
about
the
structural
consequences
of
their
policies
whereas
classical
economists
 are
paranoid
about
“distortions”
and
sanguine
about
unleashing
free‐market
dynamics.
 Weeding
out
the
inefficient
is
one
thing,
but
blanket
defoliation
is
another.
 
 But
we
need
to
talk
about
the
real
analytical
source
of
the
disagreement.
Can
money
be
idle
 in
the
sense
that
it
is
missing
from
more
valuable
use
the
circular
flow
of
income?

Can
 resources
be
really
idle
rather
than
just
appearing
to
be
so
in
a
way
that
misleads
a
 Keynesian
into
thinking
there
is
some
market
failure.
Both
sides
can
agree
that
is
true
that
 each
individual
puts
resources
to
what
is
judged
by
them
as
most
valuable
in
the
light
of
the
 constraints
imposed
on
them
by
the
decisions
of
other
individuals.
But
to
assume
that
 whatever
markets
generate
must
be
the
best
outcome
or
trajectory,
assumes
away
the
 conditions
that
underpin
any
intervention
designed
to
achieve
better
outcomes
for
 individuals
by
collective
coordination.
If
market
coordination
is
assumed
to
be
as
good
as
 humanly
possible,
clearly
government
actions
are
counter‐productive.
But
the
conclusions
 are
contained
in
the
assumptions.
They
are
a
re‐wording
of
the
assumptions.

 
 The
debate
reminds
me
of
the
dead
end
reached
in
debates
with
creationists.
What
is
 evidence
of
evolution
to
one
side
is
simply
interpreted
in
the
light
of
a
large
set
of
 preconceived
ideas
that
form
a
mutually
supporting
structure
resistant
to
analysis
one
issue
 at
a
time.
These
ideas
lie
outside
the
subject
matter
in
focus:
they
are
not
talking
about
 rocks
and
fossils;
they
are
talking
about
sexual
morality
and
countless
other
things
that
they
 regard
as
axiomatically
linked.

In
macroeconomics,
we
seem
trapped
in
the
same
pit.
It
is
 neither
obviously
true
nor
obviously
false
that
money
is
“idle”
in
slumps
and
can
be
 borrowed
with
or
without
much
concern
about
side‐effects
now
or
later.
This
is
a
research
 topic
to
explore,
not
one
to
decide
by
edict
as
a
core
assumption.

 
 36

Anon. (2006) also raises some practical objections.


It
is
rationally
harder
to
believe
that
resources
are
not
really
idle
when
they
observably
are.
 Of
course,
there
will
always
be
some
solution
if
you
let
individuals
sort
things
out.
There
is
 no
reason
to
think
that
this
must
be
the
best
feasible
solution.
Coordinated
action
is
a
 technology
taps
into
mutually
beneficial
exchange
that
require
simultaneous
actions
among
 agents.
(I
can
invest
if
you
buy
my
output.
I
can
buy
your
output
if
a
third
part
hires
me.
The
 third
part
hires
me
if
an
investment
order
comes
through.)
Government
pump‐priming
may
 permit
these
reconfigurations
to
occur
more
rapidly
than
they
(or
different
ones)
would
 have
done
otherwise.

The
ability
to
make
rapid
reconnections
in
the
face
of
a
network
crisis
 may
a
boon,
not
an
impediment.
There
is
no
reason
to
believe
that
systems
respond
to
large
 shocks
as
they
do
to
small
ones
every
day.
Why
selling
apples
on
a
street
corner
(an
example
 from
Lucas)
or
mining
for
gold
(Rueff)
is
more
efficient
than
holding
a
shovel
and
building
a
 road
is
simply
not
obvious.

 But
how
big
is
big
shock?
How
much
idle
capacity
does
there
need
to
be
to
justify
action
 confidently.
This
is
a
judgement
call
and
not
a
doctrinal
one.

 
 The
debate
has
mostly
reflected
a
clash
of
visions.
Observers
may
be
able
to
work
out
what
 each
side
is
assuming
so
that
better
assessments
of
the
merits
of
the
arguments
can
be
 made
in
the
specific
context
of
application.
Neither
side
is
going
to
convince
the
other.
What
 matters
is
which
crucial
members
of
the
audience
will
be
swayed.
And
some
may
be
aroused
 enough
to
explore
more
deeply
what
the
critical
issues
truly
are.
 What
is
the
contemporary
relevance
of
old‐fashioned
Keynesianism?
The
answer
depends
 on
the
extent
to
which
the
problem
is
caused
by,
or
reflected
in,
a
deficiency
of
total
 spending
relative
to
our
potential
to
supply.
Clearly,
over‐indebtedness
was
causing
some
 over‐spending
(and
over‐production)
prior
to
the
crisis.
We
cannot
strive
to
pump
AD
up
to
 quite
the
level
it
was
before.
We
can
rationally
argue
about
the
relative
merits
of
tax
cuts
 and
government
spending,
but
some
deep
minds
may
be
too
narrow
to
see
things
 differently.
 We
may
reasonably
regard
the
banking
crisis
as
a
negative
technology
shock
that
has
 resulted,
or
is
likely
to
result,
in
a
necessary
contraction
or
slowdown.
But
markets
(financial
 and
real)
overshoot,
and
failure
to
accept
this
is
the
principal
failing
of
equilibrium
real
 business
cycle
theory.
There
is
the
likelihood
of
an
over‐contraction
of
total
spending
and
 production.
Pre‐emptive
fiscal
stimulus
may
thus
be
a
good
idea:
a
hasty
stitch
in
time
may
 save
an
elegant
nine
later.
Early
stimulus
reduces
the
chance
of
sliding
into
the
zone
of
 output
price
deflation.
It
is
prudent
to
remain
in
the
zone
where
you
have
some
measure
of
 control.

 
 Though
they
may
disagree
on
how
to
proceed,
pragmatists
now
are
mostly
in
charge
of
 policy.
Narrow
technicians
and
ideological
dogmatists
are
not.

 
 Even
if
one
accepts
Keynes’s
relevance
for
today,
what
about
his
relevance
tomorrow
and
 beyond?
If
and
when
this
crisis
passes,
will
Keynesian
economics
go
back
into
the
antique
 display
case?

 Politicians
and
intellectuals
talk
about
the
demise
of
the
economics
of
Mont
Pelerin
and
the
 extreme
free‐market
libertarian
approach37.

But
predictions
make
fools
of
us
all.
Hayek
had

37

See Hlynur Gestsson (2009) regarding Iceland.


impressed
some
by
predicting
the
imminent
demise
of
the
Soviet
Union
for
about
70
years.
 The
USSR
lasted
longer
than
neoliberalism,
Hayek’s
fatal
conceit.

 But
only
Neoliberalism
Mark
I
may
have
failed.
Predicting
a
restoration
of
Keynes
may
be
 naïve.
What
we
see
is
a
restoration
of
pragmatism.

 
 Is
recent
government
policy
sincerely
Keynesian,
or
is
it
desperately
improvised
just
to
prop
 things
up?
Those
with
gigantic
stakes
in
the
current
system
will
do
and
say
whatever
is
 necessary
to
protect
what
they
have.
Expensive
suits
may
clothe
shabby
arguments.
The
 Keynes
“brand”
may
merely
be
there
to
lend
legitimacy
to
ad
hoc
interventions.
The
creation
 of
a
civilised
social,
economic
and
political
framework
of
a
sort
envisaged
by
Maynard
 Keynes
is
nowhere
in
sight.
"Liberal
society
yes,
liberal
economy
no"
fits
Maynard
better.

Dr
Bruce
Littleboy,

 School
of
Economics,

 University
of
Queensland
 b.littleboy@uq.edu.au

References
 (for
the
extended
version)

AAP
(2009),
“New
debit
card
to
force
stimulus
spending”,
Brisbane
Times,
March
11,

 http://www.brisbanetimes.com.au/articles/2009/03/11/1236447284368.html
 
 Jamil
Anderlini
(2009)
“China
Calls
for
New
Reserve
Currency”,
Financial
Times,
March
23,
 http://www.ft.com.
 
 Anon.
(2006),
“Time
for
a
Fiscal
Stabilization
Board?
Perhaps
Not.”
 http://www.thereconstruction.org/2006/05/13/time‐for‐a‐fiscal‐stabilization‐board‐ perhaps‐not/
 
 Anon.
(2009),
“Questions
for
Mr.
Geithner”,
The
New
York
Times,
Op‐Ed,
Jan.
20,
 http://www.nytimes.com/2009/01/21/opinion/21questions.html?partner=permalink&expro d=permalink
 
 Robert
Barro
(1996),
“Reflections
on
Ricardian
Equivalence”,
NBER
Working
Paper
Series,
no.
 5502,
March.
 
 W.
Steven
Barnett
(2009),
“And
a
Little
Child
Shall
Lead
Them
–
Economic
Recovery
in
3
Easy
 Steps”
The
Economists’
Voice,
February,
www.bepress.com/ev

 
 Robert
Barro
(2009),
“Voodoo
Multipliers”
Economists’
Voice,
February,
 www.bepress.com/ev


Gary
Becker
(2009),
“Infrastructure
Spending
as
Stimulus”,
 http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/2009/01/infrastructure‐spending‐as‐stimulus.html
 
 Andrew
Boughton
and
Michael
West
(2009),
“Wanted:
A
new
economic
theory”,
Sydney
 Morning
Herald,
http://business.smh.com.au/business/wanted‐a‐new‐economic‐theory‐ 20090206‐7z7h.html?page=‐1
 W.
Buiter
(2009)
“Banking
Crisis”,
January
29,
http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/01/the‐ good‐bank‐solution/

 W.
Buiter
(2009),
“Fiscal
expansions
in
submerging
markets;
the
case
of
the
USA
and
the
 UK”,
February
5,
http://blogs.ft.com/maverecon/2009/02/fiscal‐expansions‐in‐submerging‐ markets‐the‐case‐of‐the‐usa‐and‐the‐uk/
 Valerie
Cerra
and
Sweta
Chaman
Saxena
(2008),
“Growth
Dynamics:
The
Myth
of
Economic
 Recovery”
American
Economic
Review
March
2008,
98(1),
pp.
439–57
 
 Harold
L.
Cole
and
Lee
E.
Ohanian
(2009),
“New
Deal
prolonged
the
Great
Depression”,
The
 Australian,
Feb.
5,
p.
12
[from
The
Wall
Street
Journal].
 
 Brad
DeLong
(2006),
“Morning
Coffee
Videocast:
Time
for
a
Fiscal
Stabilization
Board
to
Deal
 with
the
Deficit?”
http://delong.typepad.com/sdj/2006/05/morning_coffee__1.html
 
 The
Economist,
Debate:
Keynesian
Principles
…We
are
All
Keynesians
Now,
 http://www.economist.com/debate/overview/140&sa_campaign=debateseries/debate19/e vents/hp/panel/?source=hpevents
 
 Alan
Coddington
(1976),
“Keynesian
Economics:
The
Search
for
First
Principles”,
Journal
of
 Economic
Literature,
14(4),
Dec.,
pp.
1258‐73.
 
 Barry
Eichengreen
(2004)
“Institutions
for
Fiscal
Stability”

 
 Henry
Ergas
(2009a),
“Five
reasons
a
fiscal
stimulus
may
not
work”,
The
Australian,
Feb.
9,
p.
 12.
 
 Henry
Ergas
(2009b),
“The
crisis
and
beyond”,
http://www.ipa.org.au/news/1809/the‐crisis‐ and‐beyond
 
 Henry
Ergas
(2009c),
“Rudd
on
road
to
disaster”,
The
Australian,
March
30,
p.8.

 
 Matthew
Franklin
(2009),
“Malcolm
Turnbull
attacks
Wayne
Swan
over
GDP”,
March
5,
 http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,25140720‐5013871,00.html
 
 Milton
Friedman
and
Anna
Schwartz
(1963),
A
Monetary
History
of
the
United
States,
 Princeton
University
Press.
 
 Joshua
Gans
(2008),
“How
exactly
did
Keynes
survive?”,
Core
Economics
blog,
November
19,
 http://economics.com.au/?p=1879


Kevin
Gallagher
(2009).
“The
developing
world
is
too
big
to
fail”,
Guardian,
5
March
 guardian.co.uk
 
 Hlynur
Gestsson
(2009),
“Ultra‐Capitalism
Killed
Iceland”,
Wall
St
Journal,
Letters,
 http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123551903590164225.html?mod=googlenews_wsj


 
 John
Huizinga,
Robert
Lucas
and
Kevin
Murphy
(2009),
“Myron
Scholes
Global
Markets
Forum:
Evaluating
 Obama's
Proposed
Stimulus
Package”,
 http://gsbmedia.chicagogsb.edu/GSBMediaSite/Viewer/?peid=439a24a984fa449a88334129 55afac45
 
 Steven
Kates
(2009a),
“The
Dangerous
Return
to
Keynesian
Economics”,
Quadrant
Online,
 Feb.
3,


 
 Steven
Kates
(2009b),
“Government
spending
spree
has
no
real‐world
benefit”,
The
Age,
 Feb.
20
 
 J.
Maynard
Keynes
(1936),
The
General
Theory
of
Employment
Interest
and
Money,
 Macmillan.
 
 J.
Maynard
Keynes
(1942),
“The
Listener”,
in
RES
CW
(1980).
 
 Paul
Krugman
(2009),
“A
Dark
Age
of
macroeconomics
(wonkish)”,
The
Conscience
of
a
 Liberal,
New
York
Times,
http://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/01/27/a‐dark‐age‐of‐ macroeconomics‐wonkish/
 
 Axel
Leijonhufvud
(1968),
On
Keynesian
Economics
and
the
Economics
of
Keynes,
Oxford
 University
Press.
 
 Bruce
Littleboy
and
John
Taylor
(2005;
2009),
Macroeconomics,
Wiley.
 Geoffrey
Luck
(2009),
“Rudd’s
fatal
conceit”,
The
Weekend
Australian,
March
28‐29,
p.
22.
 http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,25252472‐5013871,00.html
 
 Anthony
(Tony)
Makin
(2009a),
“Bad
Spend
Worse
than
No
Spend”,
The
Australian.
March
4,
 p.
12
 
 Anthony
(Tony)
Makin
(2009b),
“Why
extra
pocket
money
won’t
stimulate
the
economy”,
 The
Australian.
March
25,
p.
12.
 
 Greg
Mankiw
(2009),
“Budget
Deficit
as
a
Percent
of
GDP”
March
20,
 http://gregmankiw.blogspot.com/
 
 Allan
Meltzer
(2009)
in
Economist,
Debate,
 http://www.economist.com/debate/days/view/280
 
 Gerald
P.
O’Driscoll
Jnr
(1997),
“The
Ricardian
Non‐equivalence
Theorem”,
Journal
of
 Political
Economy,
vol.
85
(1),
Feb.,
pp.
207‐210.


Sudeep
Reddy
(2009),
“The
New
Old
Big
Thing
in
Economics:
J.M.
Keynes”,
The
Wall
Street
 Journal,
January
8,
 http://online.wsj.com/article/SB123137373330762769.html?mod=googlenews_wsj
 
 Mario
Rizzo
(2009a),
“Keynes
as
Public
Works
Skeptic”,

 http://thinkmarkets.wordpress.com/2009/01/25/keynes‐as‐public‐works‐skeptic/
 
 Mario
Rizzo
(2009b),


 http://www.american.com/archive/2009/february‐2009/taking‐the‐name‐of‐lord‐keynes‐in‐ vain
 
 Royal
Economic
Society
(1980),
The
Collected
Writings
of
John
Maynard
Keynes,
XXVII,
 Macmillan.
[CW]
 
 Wolfgang
Schivelbusch
(2006),
Three
New
Deals,
Picador.

 
 Arthur
M.
Schlesinger
(2003),
The
Politics
of
Upheaval,
1935‐1936,
Houghton
Mifflin
 Harcourt

 
 Robert
Skidelsky
(2009),
“Better
New
Deals
than
revolutions”,
Weekend
Australian
Financial
 Review,
Feb.
28‐March
1,
p.
62.
 
 John
B.
Taylor
(2008a)
“The
State
of
the
Economy
and
Principles
for
Fiscal
Stimulus;
 Testimony
before
the
Committee
on
the
Budget,
United
States
Senate”,
Nov.
19,
available
 from
Taylor’s
website,
http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/
 
 John
B.
Taylor
(2008b),
“Why
Permanent
Tax
Cuts
Are
the
Best
Stimulus”.
Wall
Street
 Journal,
November
25,
 http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/Why_Permanent_Tax_Cuts_are_the_Best_Stimulus‐ WSJ‐11‐25‐082.pdf.
 
 David
Uren
(2009)
“IMF
urges
hike
in
retirement
age”,
The
Australian,
March
10,
p.
1.
 
 Justin
Wolfers
(2009),
“On
the
Failure
of
Macroeconomists”,

 http://freakonomics.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/01/28/on‐the‐failure‐of‐macroeconomists/


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.