Vox Issue 8 - The Financial Crisis

Page 1

VOX voxjournal.co.uk

The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

Published termly by the Club of PEP at the University of York

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

The Financial Crisis A VOX Special Edition

Essays on: The Emerging New World Order Black Swans, White Swans and the Crunch Sovereign Wealth Funds The Hedge Fund Industry the Great Depression The Crash in Comparative Perspective Crises and Political Philosophy


VOX

voxjournal.co.uk

The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

“The scale of this still-on-going crisis clearly indicates that the minimalist approach to regulation of financial markets will be a thing of the past.” The Club of

PEP Journal

ISSUE VIII SPRING 2009

The financial Crisis

ESSAY CREDIT CRUNCH AND A NEW WORLD ORDER By Dr Gulcin Ozkan

PAGE 6

black swans and uncertainty By Thomas Cahill

10

sovereign wealth funds in the crisis By Jamie Manzer

14

biting bullets through bear markets By Simeon Williams

18

The great depression and today’s crisis By Charlotte Gaughan and Oliver Elliott

22

the crisis in comparative perspective By Spencer Thompson

27

Interview with professor Sue mendus By Magda Assanowicz and Ilaf Scheikh Elard

31

Photo credit: sxc.hu and Dorothea Lange.

Dr Gulcin Ozkan on what makes this crisis particular and what we can learn from it (page 6).


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

VOX

The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

__________________ VOX is a student journal that serves as a plattform for insight into topics relating to Politics, Economics and Philosophy (PEP). The essence of VOX is its interdisciplinary approach to each edition’s issue.

EDITORIAL

A

crisis (κρίσις) in the original, Greek Sense of the

word is not a hopeless situation but rather an opportunity to make a decision in the face of fresh, unprecedented challenges. In his crisis, Hercules, as the story goes, had to chose between virtue and vice. Similarly, many individuals, families, societies, nations and the world at large are in a crisis today. Neither pessimism nor optimism is helpful. Only realism combined with imagination will do. Indeed, the events of our time constitute new, empirical cases that any budding scholar is set to fathom. The present VOX edition should be read in this skeptic VOX is published trianspirit. There are no easy answers and probably the bravest and nually by the Club of intellectually honest thing to say is: I don’t know yet. PEP at the University of York and distributed There are articles highlighting the role of sovereign wealth on York’s campus as funds (p. 14) and hedge funds (p. 18). Two essays are comwell as other parative, with one examining the Great Depression (p. 22) and universities in the UK. __________________ Spencer Thompson analyzing parallels between today and the financial crisis that hit East Asia a decade ago (p. 27). Finally, we VOX committee: feature an interview with political philosopher Sue Mendus. This edition will be launched in conjunction with VOX’s hostIlaf Scheikh Elard of “The York Economists’ Panel on The Financial Crisis”, ing Cameron Dwyer Simon Fuchs on 12 February 2009, where three distinguished professors of Luke Smalley York’s Economics Department present their views on the finanMarius Karabaczek cial crisis. (For more, see p. 13). Adam Czopp If you want to get involved with VOX, drop us a line at Magda Assanowicz Lila Tennent vox@clubofpep.org. See the back inside cover to find out how Euan Edwards to contribute to the next edition. Mark Groh Anfisa Chernishova __________________ Contact: vox@clubofpep.org

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

Crises and deadlocks have at least this advantage: they force us to think. Jawaharlal Nehru

Finance, like time, devours its own children. Honore de Balzac

The Chinese use two brush strokes to write the word ‘crisis.’ One brush stroke stands for danger; the other for opportunity. In a crisis, be aware of the danger but recognize the opportunity. John F. Kennedy

Ilaf Scheikh Elard Editor


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

The CREDIT CRUNCH and the NEW WORLD ORDER By Dr Gulcin Ozkan

T

HE FINANCIAL TURMOIL that has GRIPPED THE WORLD ECONOMY since the summer of 2007 has

been widely viewed as the worst since the Great Depression in the 1930s. We are nearly into the second year of troubles and there is still no end in sight. Hardly a day goes by without announcements of gloomy earnings and losses, new bankruptcies and rising unemployment. And, forecasts of world economic outlook are getting more pessimistic by the day. Financial crises are not rare events. Since the early 1990s a large number of countries both in the industrial and the developing world have been hit by crises across the globe. The currency

crises experienced by the members of the European Exchange Rate Mechanism during 1992-93 were followed by the Mexican crisis in 1994, the Asian crisis in 1997, the Russian crisis in 1998 and the currency-cum-financial crises experienced by Brazil, Argentina and Turkey at the start of the millennium. It has been commonly agreed that the wide-scale financial liberalization had played a major role in why so many countries have succumbed to crises over this period. However, although some of these countries have suffered serious consequences, recovery has been relatively smooth for others and, more importantly, without significant repercussions for the world economy.

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

Why is the current crisis so different? This article argues that the combination of historic global imbalances, unprecedented global financial integration and a minimalist approach to financial regulation has prepared the ground for the most serious financial crisis in the post-1930s era. At the source of the global imbalances have been the Western economies, particularly the US. They have been consuming more than they produced, in contrast to the mostly Asian countries, particularly China. Put differently, people have been saving very little in the first group of countries, which meant that they have had to rely on the savings of citizens in other countries. So much so that, in 2006, the US current account deficit reached a record 6% of its Gross Domestic Product (GDP), which turned the US into the biggest debtor in the world. Any other country facing the same problem would have had serious consequences, but the US, as the world’s reserve currency, has had a relatively easy time financing its current account deficits. Asian countries have been happy to lend to the US, purchasing huge amounts of US Treasury securities as part of their foreign exchange reserves accumulation policy. However, the massive amount of capital flowing into the US had other less desirable consequences. As is known from other countries’ experiences, large scale capital inflows put upward pressure on asset prices including house prices and

stock market values. This is precisely what was observed in housing markets across the world but most notably in the US, the UK, Spain and Ireland. What was the role of financial globalization in sustaining such enormous capital flows? Clearly, if it was not for the lack of capital controls and thus such freely flowing capital, the US would not have been able to run deficits of such magnitude. Thus, the ease with which capital has been moving across the national boundaries has enabled the US to finance the gap between what it produced and what it consumed, which allowed the imbalances to go on as long as they did. One important question relates to why there was so much excess capital in the world economy during this time. It must be remembered that, throughout this period the emerging market countries had been growing at historic rates, which massively increased the world demand for oil and other energy products. This meant that demand for oil had been outstripping the supply, leading to substantial price increases. For example, the price of a barrel of oil rose to $60 in June 2005 from its value at $16 in January 1999. The trend continued and hit an all time record at $147, in July 2008. Such sharp oil price rises brought about huge trade surpluses by oil exporting countries, which has greatly contributed to the excess liquidity in the global economy. It now appears that the use of excess


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

liquidity was not managed particularly well. And this is not totally surprising. It is a well-known fact that as credit expansions get under way the quality of loans steadily deteriorates with declining repayment prospects. In pursuit of profit maximization, lenders attempt to reach more and more borrowers, relaxing credit conditions, extending lending to ever less deserving pool of borrowers. The emergence of the sub-prime market was just another example of this process. Excess liquidity had also brought about major changes in the financial system leading to increased risk appetite as well as substantial financial innovation in the form of new financial instruments with increasingly more sophisticated risk exposures. All these developments led the riskiness of the financial sector as a whole to rise throughout this period. Why were central bankers not keeping a closer eye on these developments? The past ten years had been bliss for most central bankers. The inflation targeting regime that had been adopted by many developed and developing countries seemed to have worked wonders. After experimenting with numerous alternative policy strategies to control inflation since the high inflation episodes of 1970s and 1980s, low inflation, the elusive goal for so long, was finally in reach. The pre-occupation with inflation under the inflation targeting regime, which took the form of indexing interest rate decisions to forecast inflation only, led to the finan

cial stability objective having a much lower profile during this period. Also consistent with the moves towards unfettered financial markets, regulation was taken out of the immediate control of central banks as was the case with the Bank of England. That has further weakened the authorities’ grip over the financial sector’s risk management.

If the authorities are to succeed in dealing with the current crisis, they should do their best to resist the protectionist pressures. When the sub-prime related issues were exposed, troubles started to spread from sub-prime to other areas in the financial sector, culminating in the inter-bank lending virtually disappearing. The hugely globalized nature of financial markets meant that the crisis inflicted damage well beyond the national boundaries. The collapse of the banking system in Iceland leading to loss of savings accounts by individuals and corporations throughout the UK, the collapse of a number of financial institutions in the US leading to severe losses by many across the world, for example, clearly revealed the extent of international financial linkages as never before. How to get out of this conundrum? Policy-makers have been taking fairly bold steps on monetary policy. The US Federal Reserve Board has been easing

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

monetary policy to the extent that the policy interest rates in the US are now down to nearly zero. The UK followed a similar stance and reduced the interest rates to 1.5 %, lowest in its history, with more cuts expected. The experience of Japan that grappled with recession during the 1990s provides chilling lessons. Once interest rates are down to these levels, monetary policy simply ceases to work. The next step may be what is called ‘quantitative easing’, which means injecting new money into the financial system to stimulate the economy. Many countries have also taken decisive fiscal policy actions announcing massive rescue packages. During the initial stage, this was mainly directed at bailing-out the banking sector. Increasingly, fiscal policy has been directed at jump-starting the recovery on the face of sharp contractions in the world economy. Unsurprisingly, the countries that bore the brunt of the financial collapse, such as the US and the UK, appear to be the worst hit on the real side of the economy.1 Both economies are now expected to contract during 2009.2 It is clear that this experience will have a major impact on shaping the future of global financial architecture. The scale of this still-on-going crisis clearly indicates that the minimalist approach to regulation of financial markets will be a thing of the past, at least in the foreseeable future. In the more immediate future, as is common during post-crisis periods, there will be

an immense pressure for more inward looking and more protectionist policies. A series of strikes throughout the UK this week, against foreign workers is one such example. Similarly, there have been ‘buy domestic’ provisions in some rescue packages. If the authorities are to succeed in dealing with the current crisis, they should do their best to resist the protectionist pressures. This is undoubtedly one of the main lessons from the 1930s experience. Secondly, the global financial architecture should be made ‘less illegitimate’ than today to reflect the increasing weight of newly emerging countries such as China and India.3 To that end, the Group of Seven industrial countries, known as G7, as a leading coordinating group for the world economy should give way to an alternative structure to reflect the new world order. If a contract for the future is to be drawn up, then it can only be done with the presence of countries that are most likely to be part of that future. Endnotes: 1. See, C. Reinhart and K. Rogoff., (2008) for a systematic analysis of crisis-recovery providing evidence from past crises. The paper is available as ‘The Aftermath of Financial Crises’, NBER Working Paper Series, No.14587, December 2008. 2. According to the International Monetary Fund’s November report, the UK economy is forecast to shrink by nearly 3% during 2009. 3. The use of term ‘the current financial architecture being illegitimate’ is due to Martin Wolf, Financial Times, 15 December 2008.

_____________________________ Dr Gulcin Ozkan is a Reader in Macroeconomics, in the Department of Economics and Related Studies at the University of York.


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

Black swans and the misunderstanding of uncertainty By Thomas Cahill

M

uch has been written recently about the reason-

ing behind the actions of financiers that led to the banking crisis of 2008. Commentators have attributed bankers’, what now seem ex post facto, unwise investments in mortgage backed securities (MBS) and collateralised debt obligations (CDOs) variously to greed, deception, folly or all three. Banks and hedge funds look set to increase their recruitment of risk management professionals in an attempt to minimise the likelihood of such a crisis in future. But many have begun to question whether the problem lies deeper, namely in our understanding or rather misunderstanding of risk. “In this world”, Benjamin Franklin remarked, “there is nothing as certain as death and taxes”. Life without uncertainty would, apart from anything else, be quite dull. Not least, the economy could never grow since investment, which pays a return on the risk-taking inherent in innovation, would cease. The number of genuinely risk averse persons is negligibly small, most probably for evolutionary 10

reasons. A degree of risk, therefore, is certainly desirable. But, to restate the question, has the way we have customarily thought about risk impaired our understanding of what it really is?

Humans tend to like the sort of risks that can be defined rather than those of which we cannot even conceive: Taleb’s ‘Black Swans’ or the US military’s ‘unAt least since the work of Frank Knight (1921)1, economists have distinguished between uncertainty, which cannot be computed, and risk, which apparently can and therefore admits of representation by a probability distribution function (PDF). Nassim Nicholas Taleb is not the first but is certainly the most polemic critic of this distinction. In his book ‘The Black Swan’ (2007), Taleb thunders: “Had [Knight] taken economic or financial risks he would have realized that these ‘computable’ risks are largely absent from real life! They are laboratory contraptions!”2

Yet humans tend to like the sort of risks that can be defined and given a PDF rather than those of which we cannot even conceive: Taleb’s ‘Black Swans’ or the US military ‘unknown unknowns’. What is more, for those risks of which they can conceive, in a given situation, humans prefer there to be fewer, rather than more, possible PDFs. An example of the latter is given by Ellsberg’s Paradox3. Daniel Ellsberg suggests an experiment whereby an individual is confronted by two urns, Urn I and Urn II, both containing red and black balls. One is told that that Urn I contains 100 red and black balls in an unknown composition and that Urn II contains exactly 50 red balls and 50 black balls. The individual states a preference over colour and the

urn from which he will randomly pick a ball, so that, in Ellsberg’s terminology, a red ball choice from Urn I is “RedI”, a black ball choice from Urn II is “BlackII”, etc. Before doing so he is told that if he picks his chosen colour he wins a prize and that if he does not, he wins nothing. How does he rank the different colour/urn combinations?4 By far and away the most common (and interesting) answer is that the person tested should favour RedII over RedI and BlackII over BlackI. Obviously, they are indifferent between RedII and BlackII and between RedI and BlackI respectively. The former answer is surprising because the expected utility of choosing red or black across either urn sums to 0.5. In other words, an individual subjectively maximizing their 11


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

the paper on which they are written. Arguably the panic that has gripped the financial markets since the summer of 2007 can be seen as a mass reversal of Ellsberg’s Paradox: investors who would previously have snapped up CDOs because of their status as a ‘known quantity’ prefer to look beyond the PDF handed out a priori by the experimenter. In so doing, doubt is cast on the ratings themselves, leading to further downgrades and a ‘firesale’ of what are now seen as risky assets. expected utility would be indifferent between Urn I and Urn II yet, faced with the choice of an ambiguous PDF in Urn I and a known PDF in Urn II, he seeks comfort in the known uncertainty of either BlackII or RedII.5 This type of behaviour is commonly observed in the financial markets. At the turn of the century, as asset backed securities became more complex, the credit ratings agencies Fitch, Standard & Poor’s and Moody’s continued to apply the simple three letter bond rating for CDOs that they had traditionally used for relatively more sober instruments like municipal and corporate bonds. The ratings agency plays the role of the conductor of the experiment in Ellsberg’s Paradox - who informs the participant of the PDF of Urn II - by issuing an investment grade rating (e.g. AAA) for a CDO. When rating debt that is composed of, in some way, highly risky sub prime mortgages or credit card loans as well 12

as more reliable asset tranches, one might think it reasonable to provide a range of ratings instead of just three letters. Yet if the ratings agencies do this, Ellsberg’s Paradox suggests that, notwithstanding large banks’ considerable computer power, possibly get the author to add more here to explain what they mean by computer power and how this many prevent investors from abandoning them investors will flee to the known uncertainty of a traditional, three letter grade.6 In some ways the rating acts like a good university degree from a declining institution. The degree may well be an unreliable guide to the relative quality of the student, but at least it’s reliably unreliable! When all universities start to decline in quality, a new degree becomes totally unreliable. Banks, of course, continue to attribute massive write-downs to sub prime losses and credit ratings from 2004 to 2007, have likewise come to be seen as not worth

Endnotes: (1.) Knight, Frank. 1921, 1965 (2nd ed.). Risk, Uncertainty and Profit. New York: Harper and Row. (2.) Taleb, Nassim Nicholas. 2008. The Black Swan: The Impact of the Highly Improbable. London: Penguin. (3.) Ellsberg, Daniel. 1961. ‘Risk, Ambiguity and the Savage Axioms’. 1961. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 75(4): 643-649, p.10. Incidentally, Dr Ellsberg would later become the infamous leaker of the ‘Pentagon Papers’. (4.) By assumption we ignore trivial reasons for making bets, such as choosing red because one disliked the colour black etc.. (ibid.) (5.) Gollier, Christian. 2001. ‘Should We Beware of the Precautionary Principle?’ Economic Policy 16(33): 303-327, p.310. (6.) The argument breaks down in those cases where banks design the CDOs so as to deliberately achieve an investment grade rating from a rating agency. However, it still applies in the secondary market since the rating remains with the product until maturity.

_____________________________ Thomas Cahill is a third year undergraduate reading Economics and Politics at the University of York.

VOX

The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

The Club of

PEP Journal

The VOX York Economists’ Panel on:

The Financial Crisis Thursday, February 12, 2009 6:30pm - 7:40pm A/TB/056, Alcuin College, University of York What is the future of the global financial system? Can the UK survive the implosion of the City? What can be done to get credit moving again? Does China hold the key to financial security? VOX is delighted to present this event. Hear the views of three distinguished professors of York’s Economics Department on all these questions and more: Profs. PETER N. SMITH, PETER SPENCER and MIKE WICKENS. Each member of the panel will speak for 10 minutes and then there will be approx. 30 minutes time for Q&A. For more visit: www.voxjournal.co.uk


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

Sovereign Wealth Funds In The Crisis: Praying to Perceived gods By Jamie Manzer

I

and 2009 looks to have a fair amount of hurdles. In 2007 liquidity dried up for firms and security markets. Contagion then spread throughout non-bank institutions hitting everyone from mortgage lenders to hedge funds, only to intensify in 2008 as fears mounted and sources of credit evaporated. This phenomenon called the ‘credit crunch’ left institutions floundering - struggling to meet existing financing commitments, to post additional collateral, and to cope with portfolio losses. Ill prepared and unmotivated to jump headfirst into the bank-rescue business, governments forced financial institutions to flirt with other pools of liquidity in order to recapitalize. They did. Major companies courted vast stores of wealth from the Gulf and Asia known as sovereign wealth funds (SWFs). Put simply, SWFs are “large pools of capital controlled by a government and invested in private markets abroad.” In autumn 2007 and early 2008, the world held its breath as sovereign wealth funds recapital14

t’s been a tough year

ized North American and European financial markets when governments balked at sponsoring premature, politically contentious bailout packages and recoiled at the nationalization option. Sovereign wealth funds have exploded onto the global economic scene in recent years and in 2007 it was clear that they were major players in the global financial mix. Met with intense political suspicion, the global credit crunch saw the Funds become go-to guys for financial heavyweights the world over. Shopping sprees by SWFs from the Middle East and Asia, so vital to shoring up US and European markets, raised flags of suspicion in recipient countries. The US Congress led the well-known charge against SWFs, calling for and eventually implementing robust additions to pre-existing legislation designed to monitor seemingly dodgy foreign investment. European nations followed suit, instituting their own safeguards. Then, the credit crunch came, ushering in a serious conflict of interest between national and economic secu-

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

rity. Politicians in the US and continental Europe battled, in some cases bitterly, for unilateral and multilateral regulations to protect domestic interests from dangerous investments by potentially hostile, undemocratic regimes. In response, SWFs publicly defended their clean investment histories and economists cautioned against rigid regulation.

Before things became too intense, SWFs teamed up with the International Monetary Fund (IMF) to design the Santiago Principles or the GAPP – a set of Generally Accepted Principles and Practices designed to provide guidance to SWFs regarding their management and investment strategies. This multi-

lateral approach helped quell political concerns, as did the deepening of the financial crisis. Throughout the GAPP process, a number of institutions and experts stood behind SWFs. A variety of reports and editorials praised the Funds for their investment practices and welcomed their taste in ailing US financial institutions. Late in the fall of 2007, SWFs were hailed as opportunistic, financial heavyweights – and rightly so. As major banks faced challenges, SWFs such as the Qatar Investment Authority, with some $60 billion ready for investment, saw “tremendous opportunities” to invest in faltering US financial firms. Even Europe, one of the most protectionist and defensive audiences for SWF investment, developed a taste for SWFs - though perhaps by necessity. It is argued that the crisis was big enough to encourage confidence in SWFs throughout continental Europe. In July 2007, London’s Barclays bank needed billions in fast cash to shore up a bid for Dutch rival ABN Amro (ABN), but standard credit sources looked the other way. As the story goes, Barclays President Bob Diamond jumped on a plane to Singapore and, within hours, Temasek, one of Singapore’s two SWFs, pledged $5 billion. Financial institutions and even governments were grateful for these financial heavyweights. Their investments not only recapitalized the market, but also bought lawmakers a little time so

15


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

they could avoid making immediate decisions regarding nationalization and bailout packages. November and December saw a continuation of the fall’s investment hustle and bustle. Abu Dhabi’s SWF announced, on 27 November 2007, its intentions to invest billions in the distressed Citigroup, the largest US bank. The circumstances surrounding this investment solidified the clear necessity of financing from opportunistic SWFs. Citigroup’s stocks lost 45 per cent of their value the ten months previously after losing approximately US$6.5 billion.

SWFs, like any investor, look to turn a profit, not to achieve sainthood. By mid December SWFs proved their willingness to continue taking risks when Morgan Stanley accepted a US$5 billion deal from China’s CIC, and UBS, a Swiss bank, drained US$11.5 billion from Singapore. Citigroup reached back into the pot, along with Merrill Lynch, UBS, and Morgan Stanley again in January 2008 for rapid recapitalization, in order to stabilize their finances. This injection of funds was in addition to the $27 million previously invested in Merrill, Citi, UBS and Morgan Stanley. However, it was all nice while it lasted. Cash-rich SWFs have been generous, but since January 2008 a 16

number of factors have contributed to a noticeable decline in cash-injections for major financial institutions. While investments of SWFs increased to record levels in 2008, SWFs also incurred record losses. Reuters reported some SWFs losing between 30-50% of investments within six months time. Reuters also reported that US dollar depreciation cost Funds billions of dollars. Singapore’s Temasek paid $4.4 bn for stocks later valued at $3.4 bn. This was not their only loss of the year. In fact, many stocks were trading at 50% of their original value. The manager of Norway’s Government Pension FundGlobal recently revealed that the fund has posted the worst results in its history. Abu Dhabi’s SWF, ADIA’s, modest investment in Citigroup has proved disastrous, with the equity falling from $31 a share that it paid to a low of $13 a share. Kuwait’s SWF, another regional investor in Citigroup, suffered as well. Its investment in Merrill Lynch also proved unwise when that New York–based investment bank fell on bad times and was taken over by Bank of America. SWFs, like any investor, look to turn a profit, not to achieve sainthood. They will not continue to incur heavy losses at the expense of their domestic constituency and as a result have largely ducked out of the US and European financial sector. Certainly, being of national origins, SWFs and their board have a responsibility, nay obligation, to their domestic markets to make wise

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

investment decisions. So, as the global economy enters a deep freeze, anyone wondering where SWFs are or to what extent they will factor into a miraculous recovery, should come to terms with their apparent withdrawal from the recovery mix. Why is that? SWFs are not immortal. They need to take a step back and reassess their options in order to create an optimal investment strategy. Like any rational investor, part of this strategy includes portfolio diversification after perhaps too much exposure to financial institutions. Temasek alone has 38% of its portfolio in financial institutions. Perhaps most significantly, SWF directors see the growth of their funds slowing. Global decreases in demand for oil, gas, and Asian products derailed the Funds’ rapid growth and with less to spend abroad and stabilization needed at home, it is likely that domestic spending will rise. So, while we should appreciate the help we got from SWFs in the past years, it is clear that they will not be the pot of gold some had prayed for. _____________________________ Jamie Manzer is a graduate student at the Hertie School of Governance and a researcher for the Global Public Policy Institute’s (GPPi) Global Energy Governance Program in Berlin, Germany.

Sovereign wealth funds have exploded onto the global economic scene in recent years and in 2007 it was clear that they were major players in the global financial mix.

17


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

biting bullets through bear markets By Simeon Williams

H

istory shows that disasters come and go, with the events

of 2008 and their repercussions being those of what seems to be the biggest market crises ever. The Dow Jones has lost more than 30% of its value in a single year six times before. If your great-grandfather left the stock market for dead after the 38 % drop in 1907, he missed out on a 47 % gain in 1908. If his grandkids jumped off after a 28% drop in 1974, they missed the 38% bounce the next year. 18

Given the fact that Wall Street’s primary function is to allocate capital, as the credit crisis drags on, the endless bailouts for major institutions come as quite a surprise to some in the financial community who claim to possess the greatest expertise in managing our money. Bob Lenzener, National Editor of Forbes magazine characterized the credit crunch as an economic “boxing match” consisting of many rounds of financial failures beginning with the subprime market. It is then no wonder that these factors precipitated the fail-

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

ure of Merrill Lynch before its 100th birthday, and the collapse of Lehman Brothers and the insurance giant AIG. Indeed, other institutions have sought to blame each other. For example, Citigroup stated that the Bank of England had been too “self-congratulatory” about its efforts to ease the cash shortage in banking. The spillover effects from market dislocation include the closure of many private equity and hedge fund companies as investors pull out from these assets (their assets?). Falling returns and cases of corruption increase the demand for a regulation of the hedge fund industry. Wall Street traders worry that another big wave of redemptions could further unsettle the markets. Over this decade, fewer than 15 % of hedge funds lost money. Even in the worst year, 2002, 31 % finished down. But according to estimates from HedgeFund.Net, 2008 saw some 70 % of hedge funds in the red. Nevertheless, there are some moneymakers that are having the last laugh having bet against the subprime mortgage market. A good year can vault a small player into the big leagues and thus these hedge-fund traders who make a killing are often lionized within the industry. All of which makes the big winners stand out even more. Hedge fund returns, on average, are down 20 % but one in fifty funds is up more than 30 % — a spectacular performance, considering overall stock market trends.

To a degree, hedge funds are hostage to their stated investment strategies, and the investors who shop to them accordingly. Funds that specialize in convertible bonds and stocks, for example, are among the worst performers this year because those markets have been hard hit in the financial crisis. Modern portfolio theory states that we can create any desired risk outline by combining a risk free asset (the savings account), with a less risky asset (the convertible bond fund), and a risky asset (the broad market fund), we can create portfolio with less total risk. A brief elucidation of the concept of convertible bonds is in order. These bonds act as a hybrid instrument and a good way to reduce portfolio risk while still participating in the market. Yet they are also are the “things with feathers” - to paraphrase Emily Dickinson. They participate in the upward price movements of the obligor’s stock, and yet they cannot bury themselves below the ground of their intrinsic bond value. And while their value fluctuates above a floor value, the bonds are paying interest. This risk/return profile is caused by the call option value of the bond’s conversion feature. They usually gain most when the difference between yields on corporate bonds and U.S. Treasuries is narrowing and the stock market is rallying. 2008 was their worst year, with September being the worst month for convertible bonds since 2001. Major 19


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

existing hedge funds are suffering due to the crisis in the $600bn convertiblebond market, which have lost 35% this year, with the average convertible-bond hedge fund down some 50%. This was thanks to massive recent sell-offs after failed strategies and the curb on short-selling by the U.S Securities and Exchange Commission, in the wake of the Lehman Brothers bankruptcy. In a short sale, a trader borrows stock and sells it in the hopes it can be bought back later at a cheaper price. The restriction, which was lifted 8 October 2008, prevented investors from hedging the risk that convertible bonds would fall in value. Nevertheless, convertible bonds arguably still provide investors with the greatest flexibility and the lowest risks compared to other conventional corporate bonds. The recent price decrease in convertible bonds, due to a hefty sell off, should now provide an attractive prospect to those who want to enter. New research indicated that almost 50% of major credit portfolio managers do not have “systematic and sufficiently rigorous analytical cycle management” for another crisis. So called HNWI (High Net Worth Individuals) are reducing leverage on their portfolios, depriving wealth managers of lucrative income streams that have proved core revenue streams for some of the larger wealth managers such as UBS, Credit Suisse and Citigroup. Last 20

month Goldman Sachs published reported that profits would fall an average of 25% from 2007 to 2009.

There are some moneymakers that are having the last laugh having bet against the subprime mortgage market. Wealth managers don’t normally disclose how much clients leverage, something which provides a double income stream for private banks. Clients in Asia are generally known to be more willing to borrow against their portfolio than those in Europe. “There are private banks where collateralized loans are a standard product to boost performance,” says Bernard Coucke, head of ING Europe. Yet leverage might bring some unpleasant surprises for investors who might have received loans on the basis of a portfolio including leveraged products that have now lost much of their value, reducing not only the clients’ money in the bank, but also their borrowing capacity. Wealth managers’ focus should be to continue to provide low-margin services and ride out the crisis and hope clients stick around for more lucrative products. Barclays Wealth division just published a new article entitled “The Rise of the Instividual”. This describes the growing trend of new investors in the midst of the financial maelstrom

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

caused by the credit crunch who appear to be thinking and behaving like their institutional counterparts. Online investors in particular are diversifying their investments away from equities, although a significant proportion are also trading more regularly in order to take advantage of opportunities, as high-quality securities have been sold indiscriminately and now potentially offer great value. Nevertheless, surviving members of the financial community are keen to launch their wealth management businesses in emerging markets. Since the rising asset prices and the credit binge that saw enormous potential returns over the last 25 years are now gone, the odds that China, a major driver of global economic growth this decade, will stumble seem extremely high. A Chinese downturn would send shockwaves through many economies that depend on its voracious demand for raw materials. While private clients have traditionally paid little attention to the custody of their assets, the fragility of many financial institutions, highlighted by the collapse of Lehman Brothers, focused their attention on safekeeping their wealth. Citigroup’s wealth management business brought in $3bn in the third quarter after six months of outflows. Cash deposits have been big business for banks regarded as being insulated from the worst of the crisis. I would conclude that in attempting to rebuild trust in an advisory

culture, new business often originates from internal referrals. As graduate recruiters are increasingly looking for BVAs—bright, verbal, and articulate people with great interpersonal skill, rebuilding trust in business needs to start from its employees. I would argue that wealth management services need to shift away from merely doing transactions to embrace an integral advisory culture. Traditional deposit and loan products are commodities, allowing members and consumers to easily shop rates and terms. In contrast, wealth management services and products are based on cultivating long-term relationships and trust. Although the rollercoaster markets have cooled investor appetites for equities and other assets, interest has risen in an emerging amount of less formal asset classes, such as art and wine funds, which can consider investor’s fixes for high returns amounting to 20-40% a year. Institutional investors are switching some of their assets from more expensive, specialized investment products to less expensive ones or even passive funds. The challenge is to thus improve that trust through a third-party partnership for the benefit of the credit union and the member. Sources: http://is.gd/ighq, http://is.gd/ighG and http://is.gd/ighY/ Last accessed on 19 Jan 2009.

_____________________________ Simeon Williams is a third year undergraduate student reading Philosophy, Politics and Economics at the University of York. 21


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

The Great Depression Lessons from history? By Charlotte Gaughan and Oliver Elliott

A

s the current financial crisis looks to set to worsen,

both economists and the media have become increasingly tempted into drawing parallels between current woes and the Great Depression which began in 1929 and lasted well into the 1930’s. Yet the current chairman of the US Federal Reserve, Ben Bernanke, has described the current economic turmoil as being rather different in nature to that which resulted in the Great Depression. Given that Dr Benanke has spent much of his career analysing the causes of the Depression, it would seem, that he is in a better position than most to adjudicate as to what parallels can and should be drawn from the past. Yet, despite decades of research by economists like him, there remains a surprising amount of uncertainty as to what exactly caused (and eventually remedied) the Depression. It is generally agreed that both the current recession and the Great Depression came about as the downswing of the cyclical expansion and contrac22

tion that, despite politicians claims to the contrary, appears to be an inherent aspect of a capitalist economic system. Indeed, the Great Depression was one in a long line of recessions that were often just as damaging, longlasting or global in scale. However, the Depression is distinct in that all these properties were simultaneously present. The current economic crisis has yet to reach anywhere near the same magnitude as that of the Great Depression. Forecasts suggest, at most, a GDP retraction of just a few percent and unemployment levels not reaching over 10% in the US and Europe, whilst some developing states are still registering substantial growth trends. Although unemployment is creeping up in the US and Europe, it has a long way to go to reach the levels of the 1930’s. It thus perhaps seems premature to draw too strong a comparison between this recession and that of the Great Depression. Yet there are undeniably common features to them bothfailure on ‘main street’ followed the

A destitute pea picker, Florence Thompson, a mother of seven children, age 32, in Nipomo, California, March 1936 Photopgraph by Dorothea Lange.

collapse of the financial sector, much of the banking sector defaulted or was bailed out, credit liquidity dried up, and the crisis spread from the US to the rest of the world. Explanations of the how the Depression became so serious have been attempted by all kinds of schools of economic thought. As a mainstream American economist, Bernanke follows

the traditional orthodoxy of thinking that monetary policy and its effects on the size of the money supply are the fundamental determinant of GDP. Milton Friedman, the ideological father of this ‘monetarist school’, blamed the Great Depression on monetary retraction- the money supply as measured by M2 shrank by a third between 1929 and 1933. This, Friedman claims, occurred 23


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

because the US Federal Reserve failed to support the banks that were on the verge of collapsing. As liquidity dried up, businessmen found it impossible to get loans and investment slumped. Moreover, once banks began to panic over the faltering economy, they called in loans and forced thousands of individuals and businesses into defaulting since very few had the money to pay back their loans. This led to a vicious circle of panic, banks runs and ultimately bankruptcies. If the banks had been provided with emergency lending by the Fed, according to Friedman, the economic recession produced by the consumer and stock market slump of 1929 would not have escalated to the point of a full-blown depression. The parallel with today in terms of macroeconomic policy response is clear. In an effort to avoid a repeat of the 1930’s, major economies have been very proactive in pumping huge amounts of liquidity into the banking system. Yet there is disagreement over the role the money supply may have had in perpetuating economic crisis. Economists of the Austrian school, such as Friedrich Hayek, have claimed that it was an expansion of the money supply in the economic boom period of the 1920’s that led to an excess of credit and unsustainable rises in asset prices and capital goods. This is very similar to some accounts of the contemporary economic crisis which place blame on the over expansion of credit financing without the necessary asset 24

backing. A second advocate of the Austrian school, Rothbard, claims that government reaction to this should avoid maintaining this artificially inflated money supply. Rather, one should leave the economy to naturally deflate and readjust to its normal, healthy level. Government attempts to intervene in the markets through monetary expansion can only hamper this process.

Once banks began to panic over the faltering economy, they called in loans and forced thousands of individuals and businesses into defaulting, all leading to a vicious circle of further panic, banks runs and ultimately bankruptcies. There is no doubt that Rothbard is right to question the success of government attempts to increase liquidity. Despite repeated government injections of capital, banks still remain hesitant to lend to one another or to individuals due to a lack of faith in the stability of the whole system. A key aspect of the Austrian school of economic thought, and an option being increasingly discussed within the media, is the restoration of the gold standard. As an alternative solution to a government bail-out, Nobel Prize winner John Nash has argued that an international monetary standard would curb inflation and help prevent the

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

rise of mortgage abuses. Variable rate mortgages have no doubt been a causal factor of the recent crisis and the instigation of a gold standard would bring needed stability to an oscillating market. However, not many hold this view. Bernanke believes that the use of the gold standard in the Depression made it very hard to effectively use monetary policy to restore liquidity. Towards the end of the Great Depression, it was the Structuralists who dominated the economic discourse and directed US economic policy. John Maynard Keynes famously advocated a fiscal stimulus in the form of a huge increase in government spending, with the multiplier effect ensuring any money invested in the economy would provide an even greater positive feedback effect in the economy. Indeed, this is the line President Obama had pledged to take, announcing ambitious spending plans, investing heavily in infrastructure and public services in an attempt to boost the economy and to ease unemployment. Both Obama’s and Brown’s strategy in part parallels that of Roosevelt’s “New Deal” which saw a mass cash injection and substantive government orchestrated projects. Nevertheless, the success of the New Deal continues to be debated. On the one hand, it is certain that Hoover’s policy of economic prudence and balanced books failed to resuscitate the economy. Yet whilst unemployment decreased under the New Deal, it al-

ways remained at above 20 percent. Economists Cole and Ohanian, from UCLA, have blamed the prolongation of the Depression and the subsequent weak recovery on the New Deal, suggesting that it was only the eventual onset of the Second World War which finally shifted the United States out of depression. Regardless, economists tend to be unanimous in agreement that it was the huge boom in exports following the European arms drive and later America’s own need for war mobilisation, which brought full recovery to the US economy. The large number of government issued contracts resulted in output massively increasing and a doubling in US GNP. There was also, of course, the tremendous political and social rally which caused priorities to change from fighting the depression to fighting the war. Today, governments are embarking on a mixture of fiscal and monetarist policy to try and manoeuvre their economies out of recession. Following the experiences of the Depression, some important lessons have been learnt. The international trade system has been liberalised and import tariffs spurned so as to avoid the rampant protectionism that severely hampered international trade and thus economic recovery in the early 30’s. The importance of a strong banking system in maintaining economic stability has also been fully appreciated. World governments have spent billions of dollars in taxpayers’ money bailing out ailing 25


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

banks in an effort to ensure credit is still available to firms and to safeguard people’s savings. However, comparisons between the banking systems of the 1930’s with today are limited in use given the vast differences between them. For example, many US banks in the 1930’s were not allowed to have multiple branches so banks remained small and were unable to diversify their risks. Furthermore, banking deposit insurance did not exist during the early 1930’s, resulting in panic withdrawals, which have so far been largely averted in the current crisis. Bernanke has also claimed that we have avoided one of the major pitfalls of the financial collapse of the 1930’sthe destruction of banking ‘information capital’. This information is the record of credit worthiness of individuals, which often was lost whenever a bank collapsed in the Great Depression, resulting in ever greater reticence to lend amongst the remaining banks. Such information is nowadays taken by governmental bodies. ` It is clear that the economic situation now faced by the world is quite different to that of the 1930’s. Moreover, the unresolved diversity of accounts of the Depression has left policymakers unsure as to what policies are necessary to avoid repeating it. Many of the technical pitfalls of the Great Depression have been successfully avoided but there remains a larger problem regarding the extent to which financial institutions can go unregulated. Recent 26

decades have seen many governments enthusiastically deregulate financial markets. A combination of finance sector greed and public sector connivance, coupled with an aspirational social philosophy that has pushed for an unchecked growth in consumption has led to disaster. It has caused many people to question whether there are more fundamental problems with the way we run our economic systems and whether we need to find a way of entrenching systems of financial regulation in a manner that will protect them from short-term political machinations. Of course, others would go further. Marxist critiques of the economic system have seen a resurgence in recent months. Marx suggested that the capitalist system is inherently an unstable one and that the accumulation of capital will necessarily lead to these periods of ‘readjustment’ where it will be the poorest and most oppressed people in society who will lose the most. _____________________________ Charlotte Gaughan is a third year undergraduate student reading Philosophy, Politics and Economics at the University of York. Oliver Elliott is a third year undergraduate student reading Philosophy and Politics, also at York.

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

the financial crisis in comparative perspective with the east asian case By Spencer Thompson

T

he current financial crisis

has taught us at least one thing. Although we may not all be socialist converts, given the scale and scope of the damage, it seems irrefutable that unregulated financial markets are inherently unstable. As capital expands to satisfy an exponentially increasing need to accumulate, its proliferation leads to an extension of mechanisms that outpaces government oversight, and an intensification of mobility that surpasses state boundaries. This leads to short-sightedness and risk obfuscation, the combination of which leads to investment decisions that are neither enlightened nor optimal, privately or socially. The inevitable consequence is a boom and bust situation, whereby success becomes so uncontrollably ravenous that it feeds on itself until it can no longer lift its own weight. It may seem odd, then, that during the East Asian crisis of the 1990s, the directions of neo-liberal financial institutions was to scale back state regulation and ownership. The root cause

of the crisis was deemed to be ‘moral hazard’, resulting from a divergence of the initial benefits of a risky venture, which accrue to the decision-maker, and the potential costs of failure, the probability of which are borne by the entire system rather than the agent. It would appear that either the prescription or the diagnosis was incorrect, or both. If moral hazard was indeed the cause, it was essentially a collective action problem – how, then, does it follow that the only apparatus capable of socialising such risk, and hence optimising investment decisions for each private party, should be scaled down in order to reverse or prevent the ensuing crisis? This inconsistency is even more baffling in light of Western responses to moral hazard, both historically and in modern times. Our capitalist economies are based on the socialisation of risk: limited liability and central banks are fundamental pillars of financially-propelled capitalism. Such mechanisms go unnoticed in times of 27


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

boom because their function is to influence perceptions of certainty and risk rather than to materially intervene; (for example, expectations of interest rate changes and confidence based on the institution of lender-of-last-resort). Therefore it surprises us when, in times of downturn, these establishments must actually employ their original mandates. Furthermore, we are now doing exactly what we told East Asia not to; the factors we blame for causing the East Asian crisis are the very ones we are employing to resolve our own. For instance, our ad hoc basis for bailing out banks is far more nepotistic than the selective alliances of South Korean governments, government provisions have fewer strings attached and managers are often not held responsible for unwarranted profligacy. Whereas in South Korea, many large corporations were left to fail, we have intervened not only to bail out and prop up banks, which form the bloodstream of the financial system, but have also interfered with the real economy, initially by providing commercial paper and eventually by bailing out companies, a la GM/Chrysler. The financial crisis has revealed that even our Western model of cut-throat capitalism includes some institutions that are too big to fail; the trade-off between financial stability and moral responsibility remains pertinent. Assuming that moral hazard was in28

deed to blame for the East Asian crisis, the evidence indicates not only that state intervention was not to blame for any occurrence of moral hazard, but also that government reduction did not solve the crisis once it had taken root. This inference is based on three premises. Firstly, the specific aspects of government involvement which are charged with precipitating moral hazard were either not abundant in East Asia or were already present long before the crisis, and so their existence does not explain the abrupt financial downturn; secondly, the decrease of these factors resulting from adherence to neo-liberal prescriptions of state diminution closely coincided with an exacerbation of the financial collapse rather than an expected alleviation; and thirdly, that even theoretically the suspected causes do not lead to moral hazard. As to the first point, the accusation that state interference led to moral hazard by creating an irresponsible mentality of reckless investment due to overconfidence in state support falls apart due to a misunderstanding of the relationship between government and business in East Asia. South Korean businesses, even those that would be deemed to be indispensable to the system, were often left to fail. The harsh treatment of Sambo, at one point the second largest chaebol (big business) in South Korea, after a series of bankruptcies, expounds this case. Unlike current responses, state

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

support was performance-based, and was not binding; it could be given and withdrawn from any businesses in any industry no matter how vital they would have seemed to overall stability. And whereas recent interventions have gone beyond financial sector prop-ups, trespassing into the sanctity of the ‘real economy’, any institution that was not a bank in East Asia had little or no reason to expect state support. The state takeover of Shinjin, once the largest car manufacturer in the country, contrasts sharply to United States government rescue of the ‘Big 3’ Detroit-based car manufacturers. Not only did state support in East Asia have more strings attached, but rather than bailing out businesses and leaving them to their own devices, a common undertaking in the modern case which fails to address root causes and so introduces the risk of relapse, government support involved takeover and restructuring so as to ensure future performance. It seems that our mistaken perception of East Asian cronyism is in fact a self-reflection of our own society rather than an educated assessment of reality. Moreover, if the East Asian handling of troubled corporations was cronyism, we are not only ‘guilty’ of such nepotism, which indicates a remarkable level of hypocrisy; we have also failed to operate it properly. Due to our ‘cronyistic’ democracy (labour union power was certainly an electoral consideration during the ‘Big 3’

episode), we are unable to follow in the footsteps of the East Asian states. The state tried to be selective by letting certain banks fail but in the end, it was the state that failed. The second premise is now relevant. It has been argued that state reduction not only failed to address the causes of the financial crisis, but in fact exacerbated them. By removing the coordinator of mass investments, the agencies that filled the resultant vacuum often duplicated their endeavours. Furthermore, by weakening the main determiner of resource allocation, corruption was allowed to take hold, which was most likely the case in Thailand. It could be countered that the undoing of these ‘causes’ is an inevitable feature of the East Asian Developmental State, and therefore that if the crisis was caused or worsened by state reduction, the model is still to blame. However, such an accusation cannot withstand the consideration of the current financial storm. The only explanation is that the case against government intervention is theoretically incoherent. Cronyism, as understood in the case against the East Asian state, is by definition selective, and so cannot precipitate moral hazard. In a purely capitalist system managers are often unaffected by the consequences of their decisions; this disparity between ownership and control is elucidated by reference to the public outcry against managers of failed banks continuing to receive 29


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

excessive bonuses even after it was acknowledged that their recklessness had necessitated a government bailout. In the case of deposit insurance, the depositor is not the decision-maker, and so it cannot follow that by insuring his deposits the state creates moral hazard. Far from creating moral hazard, state intervention in these cases can in fact prevent it, by ensuring that culprits are penalised, whilst still preserving financial stability. Psychologically, people tend to overvalue potential losses vis-à-vis potential gains. Any successful version of capitalism must, therefore, offset this instinctive risk averseness if it is to foster the large scale investments necessary for its initiation and preservation. When considering a situation whereby capitalism is still developing, such as East Asia at the time of the crisis, the marginal importance of wealth is far greater – lower incomes augment the conservative tendency as a failed investment decision could lead to abject poverty, not only a loss of wealth. The importance of the state in fostering confidence is therefore paramount, not to mention the fact that the government, through the facility of taxation, will be the only agent capable and motivated to engage in certain necessary investments, for example physical and financial infrastructure, or expensive research. Furthermore, investments are often complementary (consider the recent admittance that the financial system is the life source 30

of the economy) and as such, cannot be left to collapse. We obviously understand the need for intervention. Deposit insurance, one of the supposed culprits of moral hazard in the East Asian case, was executed in the early days of the current crisis. Ironically, the globalised heaven of free capital flows meant that once a few countries had fully insured depositors, everyone else had to follow suit however reluctant they may have been. Furthermore, it is often forgotten that the International Monetary Fund (IMF), the institution at the heart of the moral hazard accusations, is itself a lender of last resort, mandated to preserve global financial stability by socialising risk on a world scale. It is the ‘guardian of capitalism’. If state intervention creates moral hazard, and moral hazard is to blame for financial crisis, then it follows that the IMF itself is at least partially responsible for the East Asian crisis. Capitalism is a national project. Every version of capitalism – be it historic or modern, Eastern or Western – is inextricably bound to the entity of the state. As a neo-liberal ideal, capitalism may involve a minimal state; as a reality, this minimum is rather considerable. _____________________________ Spencer Thompson is a second year undergraduate student reading Philosophy, Politics and Economics at the University of York

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

VOX INTERVIEW:

Crises, History and apolitical political philosophy VOX’s Magda Assanowicz and Ilaf Scheikh Elard speak to Sue Mendus, Professor of Political Philosophy at the University of York.

Professor Sue Mendus Sue Mendus is Professor of Political Philosophy at the University of York and a Fellow of the British Academy. Her research expertise include modern political philosophy, liberalism and toleration. Professor Mendus has published widely and wrote books on “Feminism and Emotion” (2000), “Impartiality in Moral and Political Philosophy” (2002) and “Religious Toleration in an Age of Terrorism” (2008), amongst others.

VOX: In this mostly secular age, shouldn’t we see a re-emergence of political philosophy? That is, political philosophy as, at least, a general framework of discussion for virtues if not as a direct source of ideas? Sue Mendus: I think we should definitely see the re-emergence, and we are seeing it. Political philosophy went into a very deep decline in the period leading up to 1971 prior to the publication of Rawls’ A Theory of Justice. One of the reasons for this was that this period in philosophy was a period in which the discipline was understood very narrowly and very linguistically. It was only with the publication of ToJ that we had a very significant work of political philosophy that spoke to philosophers, economists, and political scientists. It offers an ideal theory that is meant to guide the actions of people working in political life. Subsequent to the publication of ToJ political philosophy has had an enormous revival and there have been very many debates which have important implications for policy. The School of PEP, and the 31


VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

three disciplines that go to make up PPE, seem to me very well matched. In those three disciplines you can investigate philosophical analysis, political policy and economic implications. You see that since 1971 with ToJ there are very important debates not only about justice but also equality and distribution of resources within liberal democratic societies. VOX: Some say ‘Yes, there has been revival but it has been mostly concentrated within university departments and has not influenced real political discussion’. SM: In the US, academic influence on politicians seems to be much greater than here. There are many lawyers, political philosophers, and political scientists who are significant advisers to the President. That isn’t the case in Britain. The second point is about the influence of academics on so-called ‘laymen’. That has declined quite dramatically. We do not seem to have people like Isaiah Berlin, who were great public intellectuals in the post-war period. A partial explanation of this is that the disciplines of PPE have become very technical, so it’s very difficult to engage the public in what has become quite a professional enterprise. Bernard Williams took the view that philosophy could become ‘corrupted’ by the increasing technicality of the subject and I think he’s right. I think it gets harder and harder for philosophers to persuade the public and themselves that what they do has importance. 32

We do not seem to have great public intellectuals. A partial explanation of this is that the disciplines of PPE have become very technical, so it’s very difficult to engage the public in what has become quite a professional enterprise. Williams took the view that philosophy could become ‘corrupted’ by the increasing technicality of the subject and I think he’s right. VOX: Would you agree, then, that contemporary political philosophy is apolitical? SM: A number of political philosophers say that political philosophy of the Rawlsian, liberal kind is very innocent about political reality. They think that whilst people writing on the liberal tradition and equality make gestures in the direction of the influence of philosophy on public policy, the same people are too optimistic and naïve about the extent to which there can be consensus. So the thought is, to put it quite crudely, that political philosophy is not sufficiently political. It does not deal with the realities of political life. That seems like a gesture towards a return to Machiavelli; to a recognition of the clashes that can occur in real politics.

Issue VIII - Spring 2009

VOX: Analytical political philosophy seems to be just managing the status quo. John Rawls for example says: “[T]here are many groups each equally entitled to engage in civil disobedience. Moreover they all wish to exercise this right, equally strong in each case; but if they all do so, lasting injury may result to the just constitution to which they each recognize a natural duty of justice.”* Is a constitution rather unjust if the exercise of all the legitimate claims leads to a collapse of the constitution? SM: I think it is a difficult case because Rawls does not say much about civil disobedience. That is a criticism of him in itself in not dealing with the realities. It is a question of the form ‘Isn’t Rawls being overly optimistic that all the different and conflicting demands that people make can be recognised and fulfilled within a good society?’ This is precisely the point that Rawls’ critics make of him. Although he purports to recognise the differences between people, passages like the one you just quoted indicate that he hasn’t really grasped how conflicting these situations might be. To add to that, I think those criticisms have become louder post 9/11 and 7/7. What’s being said is ‘look, these political events indicate that a kind of political philosophy that deals in distributive justice, allocation of scarce resources, is a philosophy of comfortable times’. We are not in comfortable times, either financially or politically. Rawls’ theory of justice is

the wrong approach in times of crisis. VOX: What are our priorities in times of moral confusion such as the current financial crisis? Wasn’t Rawls wrong when he said that only or especially in times of crisis we can find our moral nature? To draw a simile, a friend proves his friendship not in everday situations but in extraordinary circumstances. SM: There are (at least) two kinds of political philosophers. Some are like Hobbes, who feels that although we have a stable society, the protection of government, protection against one another, and against enemies is very precarious; at any moment it could all collapse. The security provided by the state is the thing that we have to sustain. That is our big political task: to keep the security of the state going. Other people, like Rawls, make the assumption that the state is stable. Then he says: what is the just way of distributing resources such as education and healthcare given that we are in a stable state, and given that western liberal society is not going to collapse. I wonder whether 9/11 and 7/7 put us in the kind of Hobbesian frame of mind, where once again we have to start asking: Is the state really stable? Can we afford the luxury of thinking about redistribution at the expense of thinking about stability? Were we not wrong to take our eyes away from the possibility that the stability of state will not always be with us? Perhaps Rawls was right for his time.

* Rawls, J. (1999) A Theory of Justice (Harvard University Press, Cambridge) 2nd ed. pp. 328-9]

33


VOX

VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

SM: In a book called Shame and Necessity, Bernard Williams says that we are in a condition very much like the ancient Greeks of 400 B.C. We live in a world that is disenchanted and secular, where we can’t invoke God to justify the politics we have. The modern world is in that respect very like Ancient Greece, where there aren’t Gods who will make everything right. A huge amount of political thought and 34

Call for Papers

VOX Summer Issue 2009

History will not necessarily give us a solution to our problems; the important thing is the route we took to get here. History is like a map: it tells you where you are. We have to explain morality, justify the moral order without invoking anything beyond ourselves. If people doubt that there is anything to learn from the Classics they should read Thucydides’ Peloponnesian War. When you read it, you are reading about Iraq, the Middle East. You are reading about something that happened in 400 B.C. but it comes off the page as if it was written yesterday. If anybody really thinks the Classics are redundant, I implore them to go and read that, then tell me that you haven’t got a different perspective on the problems that there are between the Middle Eastern countries. If anyone did, I would be amazed because it really does enrich one’s thought on the problems of modernity.

Theme: The Nation VOX - The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy - is calling for the submission of articles for the Summer Term Issue 2009, which will be on the wide theme of the “The Nation” (see list below). The article should be between 1000-1500 words. If you want to write, please let us know by emailing a short outline of your proposed article to vox@clubofpep.org by 22 March 2009. You might want to pick an article idea from the following list or suggest your own topic: • • •

:

VOX: Alexandre Kojève, a French philosopher who also worked at the French Ministry of Economic Affairs as one of the chief planners of the European Common Market, was asked what students should do in order to critique the system. Kojève answered, “Learn Greek.” In what sense do you think the Classics matter, if at all?

voxjournal.co.uk

m Th er e Iss Na ue tio 2 n 009

SM: There is great danger in taking historical solutions and trying to map them on to the modern world. I think we can learn from history in MacIntyre’s sense, that history explains to us how we came to be where we are. We can understand our own situation more clearly if we understand the historical path that brought us here. History will not necessarily give us a solution to our problems; the important thing is the route we took to get here. History is like a map: it tells you where you are.

philosophy is suffused with a belief that God explains and justifies. Why is it that we have rights? Locke answers in his Second Treatise: “Because God gave them to us.” Williams thinks that the task for us, like the task for the ancient Greeks, is to say how we can justify without appeal to God.

Su m

VOX: On a slightly different note: Is history having an effect on our lives? Do we ever learn from history?

The Student Journal of Politics, Economics and Philosophy

• • • •

Ethics (Morality between Nations) Identity and Vagueness (What is the Nation?) Governance (The Nation, Devolution and Supranational Bodies) Pol. History (Social Forces Leading to Nation State) Globalization and the Nation (Is the logical conclusion of globalization the end of the Nation?) The Nation as an Economic Force, or ___________ (your own article idea.)

Note: Undergraduates, graduates and academics from any degree programme are welcome to contribute. Back issues are available at: www.voxjournal.co.uk


FLEX BLE

Nationwide Opportunities Spring and Autumn 2009

Assurance Tax Financial Advisory Actuarial Consulting

Requirements: 2:1 in any subject 280 UCAS tariff or equivalent

No rigid thinking here. For instance, we’ve designed our structured development programmes to fit around you – whether you want to specialise in one specific business area or gain a broad experience. We encourage you to think laterally, as well as logically, wherever you work. And we even offer a benefits package you can tailor to your specific needs. We also look forward to seeing what you have to offer. If you’re as flexible as we are, you could soon be finding out first-hand why, for the fifth year running, we’ve been voted number one in the Times Top 100 Graduate Employers survey for offering the greatest opportunity. There’s only one number one employer – so find out why we’re the one firm for all adaptable graduates.

pwc.com/uk/careers/ Text: PwC to 85792 (Texts charged at your standard network rate.)

We value diversity in our people.

© 2009 PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP. All rights reserved. “PricewaterhouseCoopers” refers to PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP or, as the context requires, the PricewaterhouseCoopers global network or other member firms of the network, each of which is a separate and independent legal entity.


Turn static files into dynamic content formats.

Create a flipbook
Issuu converts static files into: digital portfolios, online yearbooks, online catalogs, digital photo albums and more. Sign up and create your flipbook.